Industrial Subsidies Archives - WITA /atp-research-topics/industrial-subsidies/ Fri, 10 May 2024 13:25:25 +0000 en-US hourly 1 https://wordpress.org/?v=6.6.1 /wp-content/uploads/2018/08/android-chrome-256x256-80x80.png Industrial Subsidies Archives - WITA /atp-research-topics/industrial-subsidies/ 32 32 Foul Play? On the Scale and Scope of Industrial Subsidies in China /atp-research/china-foul-play/ Mon, 01 Apr 2024 21:33:24 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=44609 Green technologies are increasingly at the center of international trade and technology policy. The Chinese government has recognized the future importance of such technologies and the related industries early on...

The post Foul Play? On the Scale and Scope of Industrial Subsidies in China appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Green technologies are increasingly at the center of international trade and technology policy. The Chinese government has recognized the future importance of such technologies and the related industries early on and is particularly active in this area. China has become a world leader in photovoltaics and battery cell production and is trying to do the same in electric vehicles, railway rolling stock and wind power. Subsidies are a key instrument in the Chinese government’s strategy to support the development of these industries. The massive subsidization of Chinese companies has led to fierce criticism in the West, however.

The European Commission accuses the Chinese government of distorting competition with subsidies for electric cars and has launched an investigation into public support for electric cars in China. The President of the European Commission Ursula von der Leyen said in her “State of the Union Address” that global markets were being “flooded with cheaper Chinese electric cars,” posing a possible threat to the European Union’s fledgling and promising electric car industry. The anti-subsidy investigation is therefore intended to determine whether manufacturers of battery electric vehicles (BEV) in China benefit from countervailable—i.e., specific and advantageous to the receiving companies—subsidies and whether these are causing or threatening to cause economic damage to BEV manufacturers in the European Union (EU).

Similar discussions have been held regarding subsidies to Chinese producers of railway rolling stock and of wind turbines. In February 2024, the European Commission had launched an investigation into China Railway Rolling Stock Corporation (CRRC) for allegedly using subsidies to undercut European competitors in a public procurement procedure. With respect to wind turbines, no official anti-subsidy investigation has been launched so far. However, leading EU officials have argued that massive subsidies to Chinese manufacturers are encouraging cheap imports from China into the EU, driving European wind turbine manufacturers to the brink of ruin.

Even though these allegations are to be taken seriously, the data situation is currently highly unsatisfactory and the requirements for legally secure interventions by the European Commission, i.e., the imposition of countervailing duties on Chinese imports, are high. And even if the requirements for legally secure interventions were met, the question still arises as to whether import restrictions would actually be in the long-term interests of the European (and especially the German) industry and consumers.

The central prerequisite for an adequate analysis and adequate policy measures is reliable data on the scale and structure of Chinese subsidies in the areas mentioned. The available data is currently scarce, partly misleading and even contradictory. Tracking Chinese subsidies is a tough and challenging task for researchers because the Chinese subsidy system is highly complex and intransparent.

The current paper assembles data on overall industrial subsidies in China from different sources and provides some new data based on the analysis of the Chinese government’s most recent final reviews of purchase subsidies for new energy vehicles and the annual reports of the most important Chinese companies in the electric car and wind energy sectors.

The data shows that overall industrial subsidies in China are significantly higher than those in large EU/OECD countries. Depending on the type of subsidies covered and the data sources and methods used, the estimates vary greatly between the different studies, however. For 2019, even according to a very conservative estimate, Chinese industrial subsidies amount to about Euro 221 bn or 1.73% of Chinese GDP. Relative to GDP, industrial subsidies in China would thus be at least three to four times higher than in large EU/OECD countries. According to a more encompassing study, the ratio could be as high as nine (relative to company sales). And this does still not include several forms of particularly hard to quantify government support measures which are arguably also of importance particularly in China. The Chinese government heavily subsidizes companies in the fields of electromobility, rolling stock and wind power, and makes the payment of subsidies conditional on production in China. With BYD (electric cars), CRRC (rolling stock) and Mingyang (offshore wind turbines), Chinese companies have got to dominate the Chinese home market for their products and are increasingly penetrating export markets as well. And even as the Chinese central government has recently abolished some of the large demand-side subsidies in these sectors— such as purchase subsidies for BEV or preferential feed-in tariffs in wind power—central and regional governments continue to support these industries through various other forms of direct and indirect subsidies. Direct subsidies to some of the dominant Chinese companies in these sectors, such as BYD for BEV or Mingyang for offshore wind turbines, have even been increased recently, helping these companies in their attempts to expand beyond China and gain a presence in EU markets.

We attempt to quantify Chinese industrial subsidies in Section 2 and discuss the challenges and potential policy response of Chinese industrial subsidies for the EU in Section 3.

DISCUSSION AND POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS

The empirical evidence presented in this paper confirms concerns and allegations raised by many trading partners against China: China strongly subsidizes those manufacturing industries which rank highly on its economic policy agenda, including many green tech industries. Here industrial policies are targeted to win and defend superiority in green technology, to convert superiority into a leading position as global supplier of key manufactured products, and to become independent of foreign technology. This policy has allowed Chinese green manufacturing industries to scale up rapidly and to start dominating the Chinese home market and increasingly also foreign markets. This is true, e.g., for solar panels or batteries for EVs, where Chinese companies have dominated the EU markets for several years now. And it is increasingly true also for BEV and wind turbines where Chinese companies are only just starting to penetrate EU markets.

The very comprehensive and opaque Chinese subsidy system blurs the difference between domestic subsidies which do not distort trade and subsidies intended to help domestic companies to conquer export markets and thus are trade distortive. Two trading partners stand out, here, as the most important export markets for China, the US and the EU. Each of the two has its own agenda when it comes to dealing with China. The US has set the agenda with a plethora of legislative acts to enforce the “produce in America” strategy. The Inflation Reduction Act is the quantitatively largest one and supports the rise of local content in US non-fossil manufacturing through producer and consumer tax credits. In addition, BEV imported from China face a hefty import tariff of 27.5%. Hence, a trade and tech war with China trying to decouple the country from state-of-the-art IT technology is envisaged by the US through, e.g. restricting high tech exports to China and screening US foreign direct investment in China on risks of losing technology superiority.

So far, the EU has no trade or tech war on its agenda. The European Commission has made clear, however, that is prepared to take stronger actions against subsidized imports from China. In line with this, it has officially launched an anti-subsidy investigation into the import of BEV from China in October 2023. And in February 2024, it had launched an investigation into Chinese rolling stock manufacturer CRRC for allegedly using subsidies to undercut European competitors in a public procurement procedure in Bulgaria, applying for the first time the EU’s newly enacted “Foreign Subsidies Regulation”. In the BEV case, the European Commission argues to have found sufficient evidence demonstrating that imports of BEV from China benefit from subsidies that allow them to rapidly increase their market share in the EU thus posing an imminent threat of injury to the EU domestic industry and de-motivating domestic investment into badly needed full electrification. If these allegations are confirmed in the investigation, the EU could impose retroactive countervailing tariffs against BEV from China. 

Pros and cons of an EU intervention

Seen from the textbook lens, there is a strong case against the introduction of such tariffs (restrictions) on subsidized imports. This is substantiated by the view that subsidies are ‘gifts of the donor’ which raise the real income of recipients of gifts (the European consumers) while strengthening their comparative advantages in other non-subsidized sectors. An increase of tariffs/import restrictions on BEV or other imports of green technology products from China would likely lead at least in the short term to higher costs for green technology products in the EU and could make the green transition of the EU economy more expensive and also slow it down. This applies even more to import restrictions on those green technology products for which the EU industry currently has too little capacity to meet the increasing domestic demand such as EV batteries or wind turbines.

Yet, the textbook lens may neglect a dynamic perspective including geopolitical externalities, path dependencies, and the issue of technology control in key industries. Battery cell technology, for example, is not only one of the key technologies in the energy transition, but also qualifies as a general purpose technology (GPT). Early mover advantages and spillovers into related sectors (aviation, underwater shipbuilding, medicine) could make it beneficial to push such technologies and to avoid one-sided dependencies on systemic competitors like China. From a geoeconomic perspective, import restrictions reducing the (increase in) imports from China of products vital for the green transition may, in addition, be considered a welcome contribution to reducing the EU’s reliance on China (‘de-risking’). Or it may even be considered necessary for strengthening national security given the espionage or sabotage risks which are currently being put up against the imports of wind turbines or connected cars (BEV) from China especially in the US.

On the other hand, we also need to consider that the EU has much higher stakes in the Chinese economy than the US as witnessed by the much higher share of EU investment in China and the far greater reliance on imports from China of the EU as compared to the US. Due to China’s strong position as a production base for European firms and as a source of many critical products for the EU market, its retaliatory power against the EU is higher than against the US.33 Hence, the costs for EU industries and consumers of import restrictions on subsidized Chinese goods could increase considerably if the Chinese government were to respond to with countermeasures such as export restrictions on inputs on which the (green tech) industries in the EU are heavily reliant, such as refined rare earths. Such export restrictions would harm the EU industry not just on the internal EU market but also with respect to its exports to China or third-country markets. And export restrictions on necessary inputs are just one of a myriad of possible countermeasures through which China could harm EU companies in the industry directly affected by EU measures or indeed any other EU companies trading with or producing in China. This is likely one reason for why German automobile manufacturers which are heavily engaged in trading, production and R&D in China are rather skeptical about the EU’s investigation into BEV imports from China. 

But even without considering possible Chinese retaliatory measures it is far from clear, whether and to what extent EU industry would actually benefit from restrictions on Chinese imports. Take again the case of EU import duties on BEV from China, for example. First, these tariffs would also affect imports of BEV manufactured by European (German) companies in China.

Second, the (direct) effect of EU import tariffs on BEV from China would be restricted to the EU market, only. On third country markets (and in China itself) BEV produced in the EU would still have to compete against subsidized BEV from China without countervailing duties. Third, the effects of import restrictions and thus less intense competition on EU industries’ incentives to invest in R&D and in cost efficient production facilities are ambiguous (from a theoretical point of view).

From a purely industrial economics point of view tariff protection or subsidies for the EU industry could be justified if subsidized imports from China would hinder the EU industry to scale up and achieve the economies of scale necessary to compete internationally. In our view, it seems likely, however, that the industry will be able to substantially increase production in the EU despite increasing Chinese imports. Given the strong increase in demand and the comparatively high transport costs for BEV (or for other heavy and large green energy products such as wind turbines) we would expect that manufacturers will expand production near consumers to reduce shipping costs, as technologies mature. At least in the medium term we would thus expect companies producing in Europe to have a substantial advantage in serving EU customers (the more so as import tariffs for BEV into the EU now stand at 10% even without additional countervailing duties). We would thus also expect Chinese BEV manufacturers to build up production capacities in Europe to serve the EU market (as we have already observed for Chinese producers of EV batteries).

What should the EU do?

In our view, there is a case in favor of driving forward the current EU proceeding against BEV imports from China, and to use the information obtained in this proceeding and the pending decision to enter into negotiations with the Chinese government and to try to persuade it to abolish some the Chinese support measures that are particularly harmful to the EU industry. Given the current weak macroeconomic situation in China, the focus of China’s government on its political conflicts with the US and, at the same time, the relative strength of China’s green product industries, we believe that there is currently a realistic chance for such negotiation to be successful.

bc6aff38-abfc-424a-b631-6d789e992cf9-KPB173_en

To read the abstract published by the Kiel Institute for the World Economy, click here.

To read the full policy brief, click here.

The post Foul Play? On the Scale and Scope of Industrial Subsidies in China appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Whole-of-Nation Innovation: Does China’s Socialist System Give It an Edge in Science and Technology? /atp-research/whole-of-nation/ Tue, 05 Mar 2024 16:16:20 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=43547 This brief is part of a special series organized jointly by the University of California Institute on Global Conflict and Cooperation (IGCC) and the Mercator Institute for China Studies (MERICS)....

The post Whole-of-Nation Innovation: Does China’s Socialist System Give It an Edge in Science and Technology? appeared first on WITA.

]]>
This brief is part of a special series organized jointly by the University of California Institute on Global Conflict and Cooperation (IGCC) and the Mercator Institute for China Studies (MERICS). This analysis was originally presented at the Conference on the Chinese National Innovation and Techno-Industrial Ecosystems in Berlin, September 5–6, 2023.

China wants to become a science, technology, and manufacturing superpower by upgrading and modernizing its industrial base and concentrating the nation’s innovation resources around strategic priorities. However, it is difficult for the state to integrate innovation resources because of the gap separating universities and research organizations from industry, which impedes the translation of scientific output into technological prowess. By contrast, Beijing has been much more successful at directing industrial development. As a result, achieving a modernized industrial base is now the dominant framework for Chinese policymakers as they pursue technological self-reliance.

Key findings

  • Official calls for a new-style whole-of-nation effort in China are primarily aimed at directing Chinese researchers and business to tackle key techno-industrial bottlenecks. This sense of urgency is necessary to overcome barriers between academia and industry. 
  • Public information does not support the idea that Beijing has a shortlist of top priorities that it is concentrating the nation’s resources on. 
  • By refusing to outsource and preferring to maintain a large share of its economy in manufacturing as opposed to services, China is pursuing a different development path than most developed countries. This will impact trade relations with other nations. 
  • Beijing’s fixation on national sovereignty and self-reliance complicates interaction with foreign stakeholders. Its long-term vision for China’s industrial and innovation policy envisions a limited role for foreign technology firms in the Chinese market.

Introduction

On October 17, 2023, the United States issued its second batch of export controls on advanced computing and semiconductor manufacturing items to China, expanding its “small yard, high fence” approach to include more technologies and impact more countries. The European Commission has similar concerns about technology leakage but is more circumspect in its response. Its economic security strategy calls for partnering with allies, promoting competitiveness, and protecting interests “in a proportionate and precise way that limits any negative unintended spillover effects on the European and global economy.” The Commission intends to complete a security review of four critical technologies in 2024.

China is a major catalyst of the global trend of scientific and technological nationalism, with its party and state leader Xi Jinping doubling down on national security ever since he came to power in 2012. For instance, in 2016 Xi called for national self-reliance and self-empowerment (自立自强) in key and core digital technologies at the inaugural Work Conference for Cybersecurity and Informatization, predating U.S. sanctions by several years. Science, technology, and innovation (STI) have become the main arena of global strategic competition, Xi announced in 2022, adding that the contest over the scientific and technological commanding heights of the global economy has never been more intense.

Diverse geopolitical actors across the United States, European Union, and China have different interests, priorities, and approaches in securing key technologies. But the net result  is that science, technology, and innovation have become increasingly political. Policy is now driven by national security concerns, which creates friction in international networks. Joint publications between U.S. and Chinese researchers are already declining.

Chinese and Western firms face questions about their loyalty at home and abroad, as well as complex regulations for exporting data and goods involving strategic or critical technologies. 

To understand this trend, this brief offers a thorough analysis of Beijing’s vision for its innovation and industrial systems based on close readings of high-level policy documents and commentaries.

Collectivizing industrial efforts

The Communist Party of China has a long history of directing industrial development, combining domestic goals of providing basic goods, jobs, and economic growth with notions of self-reliance and national security that emphasize international competition. The notion of the “new-style whole-of-nation” system (NSWN, 新型举国体制) takes inspiration from this history. It has gained prominence since the fourth plenum of the 19th Central Committee in 2019 as Beijing seeks to capitalize on the socialist system’s unique ability to “concentrate power to do great things (集中力量办大事).” The 14th Five-Year Plan of 2021-2025 presented the NWNS system as a key component of “the battle for key and core technologies.” 

The NSWN concept refers back to the whole-of-nation approach of the late 1960s and early 1970s, which enabled China to develop nuclear weapons and ballistic missiles in the space of just a few years, despite being cut off from its major source of technological knowhow through the Sino-Soviet split. Under Chairman Mao, the effort had been overseen by the Central Special Commission (中央专委), which was discontinued in the 1970s.  Similarly, President Xi set up a Central Science and Technology Commission (中央科技委员会) in March 2023 to oversee the NSWN approach and reform the Ministry of Science and Technology into its supporting agency.

By centralizing control of STI in China, these changes go against the central tenets of the “reform and opening up” (改革开放) policy that began in the late 1970s. These included the depoliticization of science and technology, as well as the devolution of power over resource allocation to markets and local actors. Still, the presence of a large and vibrant private sector distinguishes the NSWN approach from its 1960s predecessor. Acknowledging the importance of entrepreneurship to innovation, Beijing looks to enlist the private sector through a mixture of incentives, regulations, and political steering. This structural tension in China’s socialist market economy is summarized by the ideal of “an efficient market and an effective government (有效市场和有为政府).”

A network of fitness centers to break local barriers

To understand how China’s mixed economic system works for innovation and industrial policy, it helps to see the NSWN system as a variation of the country’s national Olympic program. Sports programs in China are discussed in terms of a whole-of-nation system. Both China’s highly successful Olympic programs and its current effort to break foreign technological bottlenecks combine training and grassroots competitions with a multi-tiered national selection program focused on outperforming international competitors. In this approach, the state delegates the day-to-day organization and refereeing of the program to trusted partners. 

In the NSWN system, objective external indicators measure the program’s effectiveness. Absent medal tallies, export volumes and values have become the benchmark for industrial innovation. Success in overseas markets makes a firm more worthy of government support. Domestically, Beijing allows foreign firms like Apple and Tesla to sell products in a controlled setting while monitoring the market share of domestic frontrunners to assess their competitiveness.

These mechanisms compensate for a lack of trust in local data on the fitness of Chinese businesses, and this “export discipline” targets firms as well as local officials. In a previous phase of China’s state-led development model, local officials had wide room for policy experimentation, including by launching industrial and innovation zones, creating pilot and demonstration projects, and in allocating investments. However, this sometimes led to local protectionism. The NSWN system is part of a larger trend to restrict local discretion in how these programs are implemented. 

Too many stakeholders to concentrate

The whole-of-nation approach enables other actors to vie for central government attention. Following previous mission-oriented programs, it stands to reason that the NSWN system would appoint issue owners in a handful of technology areas who would each bring together various stakeholders, formulate benchmarks, allocate resources, assess progress, and lobby Beijing for funding and favorable policies.

The NSWN system aligns with recommendations by professors Yutao Sun and Cong Cao, who point to more recent precedents, such as the National Integrated Circuit Industry Investment Fund, China’s development of high-speed rail, or the 16 science and technology megaprojects for the 2006 to 2020 period. The latter successfully spearheaded Beidou’s satellite navigation, Huawei’ 5G next-generation mobile Internet, and the C919 commercial aircraft, which were supervised respectively under a military research organization, a state-affiliated think tank, or a state-owned enterprise (SOE).

These organizations are almost certainly lobbying for state support in Beijing. It has become hard for outsiders to read the outcome of these negotiations. For instance,  a new batch of 15 science and technology (S&T) megaprojects was announced in the S&T Five-Year Plan for 2016-2020, to which new-generation artificial intelligence was added in 2017. Details on these megaprojects and their relative centrality in the innovation chain would be in the Science and Technology Mid- to Long-Term Plan for the 2021-2035 period, but that plan was never published. Using these limited resources, Barry Naughton, Siwen Xiao, and Yaosheng Xu do a remarkable job of puzzling together what the NSWN system might look like.

However, there is no public evidence to suggest that this approach has become dominant. Chinese commentators rarely discuss which technologies should be prioritized on what grounds, how many technologies China could realistically concentrate resources on, or who should bring the nation together in a specific technology area. As a result, there is no current authoritative list of key and core technologies—the best proxy is a list of 35 “stranglehold” technologies such as lithography machines, operating systems, and aircraft engines issued by a state-affiliated newspaper in 2016. There is also no matching list of topic owners or even institutional platforms for “national teams.”

Instead, China’s innovation and industrial policy is still fragmented across many partially overlapping platforms and initiatives. Naughton, Xiao, and Xu identify around 50 bottleneck and competitive-advantage technologies. But this number is too large and the technology areas are too big for this to amount to an effective concentration of resources. Analysis of research funding, investment data, publications, and patents also does not show a clear prioritization.

Instead of focusing on specific technologies and sectors, public discussion on the NSWN focuses on improving synergies between industry, universities, and public research institutes (产学研融合).

Xi wants a complete, advanced, and secure industrial base

The 14th Five-Year Plan (2021-2025) calls for building a modern industrial base (现代产业体系), linking the project to China’s goal of becoming a manufacturing powerhouse (制造强国). Similar terms have been used since at least the 17th Party Congress of 2007. In May 2023, President Xi elaborated on the closely related term of a “modernized industrial base” (现代化产业体系). To build a modernized industrial base that is complete, advanced, and secure, President Xi told the Central Commission for Financial and Economic Affairs (CCFEA) that China should make use of scientific and technological revolutions, capitalize on its industrial prowess, and promote global innovation. Xi also argued that China should not simply push out low-grade industries but instead work to upgrade them.

This last remark is consistent with the leadership’s emphasis on the “real economy.” President Xi repeatedly warns against Chinese modernization “losing touch with reality” (脱实向虚), for instance during his trip to Guangzhou in April 2023. Zheng Shanjie, the director of China’s chief planning agency, the National Development and Reform Commission, elaborated on this in Qiushi, the party’s main theoretical journal.

“Today’s modernized economies rely on the real economy to generate growth and remain resilient. One of the main reasons some countries lost their lead or fell into the so called “middle income trap” and experienced long periods of stagnation is their neglect of the real economy, their failure to modernize their industrial system. … Traditional industries make up most of China’s manufacturing prowess. We can’t simply push “low-grade industries” out. Instead, we should guide and support firms in traditional sectors to upgrade. … The emerging industries are the pillars of future development, but we shouldn’t blindly pursue foreign novelty.”

China should not let its manufacturing base be hollowed out like the United States’, adds Cui Fan, a professor at China’s University of International Business and Economics and the director of the research unit of the China Institute for WTO Studies. Cui argues for including financial and digital services that support industrial activity into the definition of the “real economy” and excluding only those activities that “directly create money with money.” This is consistent with recent government clampdowns on “the disorderly expansion of capital,” particularly real estate speculation. 

The insistence on including traditional industries like steel, coal, and shipbuilding—as well as the SOEs that dominate them—follows Communist orthodoxy. It also seeks to hedge against an escalating trade conflict with the West. Industrial bases are important in times of crisis, as COVID-19 was a stark reminder. They are especially important to China as global technological competition intensifies, because China’s leverage is based less on the uniqueness of its technologies and more on its ability to produce large volumes quickly and cheaply. Replacing China’s global role in critical raw materials, solar panels, active pharmaceutical ingredients, and telecommunications equipment would be an economic challenge for the West rather than a technological one. To keep the cost of decoupling high for foreign governments and multinationals, China needs to retain its central position in global supply chains.

However, due to rising labor costs, the contribution of manufacturing to China’s gross domestic product (GDP) declined 6 percent between 2008 and 2020 to 26.3 percent, calculates Professor Cui. After, Beijing was able to arrest the decline but only slightly, growing the figure 1.1 percent in 2021 and 0.3 percent in 2022, which inadvertently caused China’s debts to balloon. Beijing’s insistence on boosting industrial production also demotes other national goals, such as making China less reliant on export markets, reducing carbon emissions, and raising consumption and quality of life under the rubrics of “common prosperity” (共同富裕). 

Policy implications

The new-style whole-of-nation system and the modernized industrial base represent two partially overlapping responses to the risk of foreign technological containment. Whereas the former focuses on generating intellectual property through strengthening the innovation chain, the latter seeks to upgrade the Chinese manufacturing sector to climb up the global value chain. The two policies side-by-side expose the contradictions of China’s two goals of technological self-reliance and economic de-risking.

The relative importance of the modernized industrial base in the Chinese-language debate is clear by the recent flurry of publications, including by leading ministries and think tanks. These writings consistently call for consolidating leads, upgrading traditional industry, and accelerating innovation through the NSWN system, in that order. The tensions between these goals are rarely discussed. This paper highlights some of the more obvious contradictions, such as concentrating resources on all technologies of possible importance. The program also creates changing state-market relations, which is leading to tasking the most conservative stakeholders—such as military organizations, legacy research labs, state-owned enterprises, and public financial institutions—with organizing innovation and nurturing a start-up scene. China’s policies encounter further contradictions in their attempts to upgrade manufacturing capacity without outsourcing polluting and labor-intensive industry segments to other countries and in promoting exports, international collaboration, and in-bound investments as a means to reduce foreign reliance.

Some degree of ambiguity may work in Beijing’s favor, as it provides flexibility and cover in achieving its de-risking and self-reliance aims. However, implicit restrictions on the public debate also blunt the recommendations of policy advisors. A glaring absence in the emerging vision is that of large private and foreign companies. Despite the large contributions of tech giants and multinational corporations to China’s past innovation and productivity gains, as well as the importance of overseas returnees in China’s innovation landscape, the outside world features either as a source of risk—through the technological strangleholds—or as an export market whose absorption of more and more Chinese goods validates the country’s progress.

Foreign firms may be able to convince local Chinese interlocuters that their contributions should be recognized and accommodated, especially if their branches are well integrated in local value and innovation chains. This approach is likely to succeed some of the time, and in some places and sectors. But the overarching long-term vision for innovation and industrial policy that currently dominates in Chinese policy circles follows the logic of China’s dual circulation strategy (双循环), which primarily aims to compartmentalize and reduce China’s exposure to external shocks. Even though China may never realize this vision in full, it is wise for Western stakeholders to take it seriously and formulate their own de-risking strategies.

Conclusion

Based on China’s track record, the NSWN approach will be most successful in areas where there is an established technology that China can emulate—such as atomic bombs, navigation satellites, space stations, or high-speed rail. Lithography equipment may also fit this mold. By contrast, China’s successes in solar panels, energy vehicles, telecommunication equipment, and various digital platforms have relied much more on private entrepreneurship. Looking forward, the first policy by the Central Science and Technology Commission focuses on “future industries”, many of which require corporate initiative, not least artificial intelligence. The key metric for success of the NSWN approach will be in whether it can spur innovation by tech entrepreneurs. So far, that looks unlikely.

Jeroen Groenewegen-Lau is Head of Program of “Science, Technology and Innovation” at MERICS.

Jeroen-Whole of Nation Innovation-02.24.24

To read the full brief as it is published on MERICS’ website, click here.

To read the full brief, click here.

The post Whole-of-Nation Innovation: Does China’s Socialist System Give It an Edge in Science and Technology? appeared first on WITA.

]]>
On a Collision Course: China’s Existential Threat to America’s Auto Industry and its Route Through Mexico /atp-research/us-cn-mex-autos/ Tue, 20 Feb 2024 12:28:30 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=42308 A Bad Bargain The introduction of cheap Chinese autos – which are so inexpensive because they are backed with the power and funding of the Chinese government – to the...

The post On a Collision Course: China’s Existential Threat to America’s Auto Industry and its Route Through Mexico appeared first on WITA.

]]>
A Bad Bargain

The introduction of cheap Chinese autos – which are so inexpensive because they are backed with the power and funding of the Chinese government – to the American market could end up being an extinction-level event for the U.S. auto sector, whose centrality in the national economy is unimpeachable.

 

The U.S. auto sector accounts for 3% of America’s GDP. It is annually responsible for tens of billions of dollars of annual research and development spending. It supports an entire ecosystem of manufacturers, from steelmaking to semiconductor fabrication. And for nearly a century, it has provided reliable, well-compensated employment for millions of American workers of various levels of educational attainment, making it a pillar of the American middle class. As such, the U.S. auto industry’s health has been the years-long focus of U.S. trade policy, and a more recent focus of U.S. industrial policy. This includes longstanding tariffs on imported light trucks, and more recent rules of origin (ROO) content requirements for vehicle imports from Mexico and Canada, as well as clean vehicle consumer tax credits that reward domestic production as U.S. automakers undertake an industry-wide pivot to the manufacture of EVs.

The U.S. auto sector and its extensive domestic supply chain, however, face a growing threat from Chinese competitors, buoyed by the Chinese state. While direct imports of Made in China automobiles have until now been extremely limited, China’s auto sector is hardly the uncompetitive laggard of decades past. Thanks to the Chinese Communist Party’s (CCP) industrial planning and generous assistance that began in the wake of the 2009 financial crisis, its state-owned and state-supported manufacturers are poised to dominate the burgeoning global EV market. China is estimated to have spent tens of billions of dollars to create an auto sector ready to take advantage of the clean energy shift, with support including tax breaks, favorable lines of credit, land use agreements, extremely limited import competition, and often direct subsidization. Chinese automakers have also benefited from mandatory joint ventures with and forced technology transfers from foreign firms seeking to gain access to the vast Chinese auto market. And, most egregiously, they benefit from the use of forced labor in their supply chains.

The state support has paid off. The Chinese auto industry’s growth has been exponential. The country became the world’s leading auto exporter in 2023, selling cars in Europe, Australia, Africa, Mexico and Southeast Asia, and Chinese automakers lead the world in EV production and sales by wide margins. China’s technological lead and its extensive supply chains, particularly for critical battery raw materials and components, are deep and secure because of its defined and deliberate industrial policies. Beijing has prioritized reducing dependencies on other countries, which in turn makes the world increasingly dependent on its own supply chains.

The CCP’s objective is no secret: Global market dominance, made explicit in economic blueprints like Made In China 2025 and China’s most recent Five Year Plan. And the results of China’s industrial bets – mammoth entities like BYD, SAIC Motor and battery maker CATL – are this effort’s champions. They are expanding rapidly, without consideration to supply and demand and basic market forces, so much that the Chinese auto sector is estimated to have a production overcapacity of millions of vehicles per year. That overcapacity is now facing outward, in search of new markets to soak up the largesse.

China’s automakers currently face significant barriers to entry into some western markets, including the United States. The European Union in 2023 began an investigation into the raft of subsidies that underpin Chinese auto exports’ competitiveness, while U.S. tariffs have successfully kept these cars, electric or otherwise, off American highways.

But Chinese automakers are not idle. BYD, which became the world’s largest EV manufacturer in 2023, is building a factory in the heart of the European Union and is among half a dozen Chinese companies preparing to manufacture in Thailand, thereby gaining access to nearby markets through regional trade pacts.

More alarming, however, are Chinese firms’ heavy spending on plants in Mexico, through which they can access the United States by way of the more favorable tariffs under the United States-Mexico-Canada Agreement (USMCA). This strategy is, in effect, an effort to gain backdoor access to American consumers by circumventing existing policies that are keeping China’s autos out of the U.S. market.

This is an auto industry backed by the Chinese state. It has invested heavily in foreign markets in order to access more of them. And there is cause for alarm that Chinese vehicles and parts will only increase their access to the U.S. market, overcoming existing tariffs and evading existing trade enforcement measures, to directly challenge domestic automakers and threaten the jobs of millions of American manufacturing workers.

The United States must adopt a proactive and evolving strategy to stymie the CCP’s penetration. Washington should raise tariffs further on Made in China vehicles, tighten and fully enforce the USMCA’s ROO so they are not allowed to leak in, and exclude from the pact’s preferential treatment components and vehicles made by companies headquartered in non-market economies like China. Washington must strictly enforce its own industrial policies, like the clean vehicle tax credits included in the Inflation Reduction Act, so that upstream content and raw materials from China do not benefit. Washington also must fully implement and enforce the Uyghur Forced Labor Prevention Act to keep goods and inputs produced in the Chinese police state of Xinjiang and by other oppressed minority ethnic groups out of the U.S. market, so that none of this content reaches American consumers.

The threat posed to the American auto industry by heavily subsidized Chinese imports is significant, and the level of its severity will depend greatly on how federal policymakers respond to it. A dedicated and concerted effort to turn those imports back requires greatly strengthened trade enforcement and fully implementing existing domestic industrial policies. This effort should be undertaken immediately; there is no time to lose.

on-a-collision-course-report-final-022324

To read the introduction and takeaways as it is posted on Alliance for American Manufacturing’s website, click here.

To read the full report published by Alliance for American Manufacturing, click here.

The post On a Collision Course: China’s Existential Threat to America’s Auto Industry and its Route Through Mexico appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Rethinking International Rules on Subsidies /atp-research/rethinking-international-rules-on-subsidies/ Fri, 08 Sep 2023 21:16:37 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=39254 The World Trade Organization needs an updated toolbox in the face of rising industrial policies across the globe. “The United States should lead the effort to reshape the global rules...

The post Rethinking International Rules on Subsidies appeared first on WITA.

]]>
The World Trade Organization needs an updated toolbox in the face of rising industrial policies across the globe.

“The United States should lead the effort to reshape the global rules to better serve its own interests and the international trading system’s changing realities,” claims a new Council Special Report, Rethinking International Rules on Subsidies. The authors, CFR trade experts Jennifer A. Hillman and Inu Manak, contend that such an effort “would give the United States a powerful tool to address its twin concerns over competition with China and fighting climate change. It would also allow the WTO and the world to come closer to a more equitable, resilient, and sustainable international economic order.”

The report examines the growing reliance of the United States on using domestic subsidies to address global challenges: “the [Joe] Biden administration has maintained and expanded on the [Donald] Trump administration’s tariff policy, defended at the time as helping the United States compete globally against a rising China, by introducing major new subsidy programs. Importantly, the primary motivation for those efforts falls into two buckets—to counter China and to fight climate change.” That adoption of industrial policy “has prompted cries from across the globe that the United States is fostering unfair competition and breaking the rules it helped shape as part of the World Trade Organization (WTO).”

In the aftermath of simultaneous political and economic crises, “the perception of countries’ urgent need to build up their resiliency in critical goods and services, coupled with the existential threat of climate change, means that moving toward industrial policies and increasing subsidies is warranted and indeed essential,” Hillman and Manak write. “However, the urgency of the problems does not mean abandoning well-founded concerns that industrial policy—done wrong—can stifle innovation, create substantial inefficiencies, exacerbate the concentration of corporate power, waste precious taxpayer funds, and fuel crony capitalism.”

The authors outline the deficiencies of the current international rules governing subsidies and provide recommendations. In particular, Hillman and Manak highlight the failure of many WTO members to report their subsidies, the ineffective remedies available, and the lack of special recognition by WTO rules of beneficial subsidies aimed at tackling climate or public health challenges, among other issues.

To lead the charge on reforming the WTO rules, the authors propose that the United States should

  • “revisit what constitutes good and bad subsidies and propose limiting overall subsidy levels while carving out areas in the common international interest”;
  • “encourage countries to disclose their subsidies, both by using the incentive of a ‘safe harbor’ for subsidies that have been properly notified and enforcing penalties for those that consistently fail to make timely notifications of their subsidies”; and
  • “strengthen the penalties for noncompliance with international subsidies rules.”

“At its core, one of the WTO’s critical roles is to help its members draw the line between protectionist measures and sound industrial policies, while ensuring that wherever that line is drawn, it does not unduly privilege some or harm others,” Hillman and Manak conclude. “To do that in the face of rising industrial policies across the globe, the WTO needs an updated toolbox.”

Jennifer Hillman is the Senior Fellow for Trade and International Political Economy and Inu Manak is the Fellow for Trade Policy at the Council on Foreign Relations.

Rethinking International Rules on Subsidies

 

To read the full Council Special Report, please click here.

The post Rethinking International Rules on Subsidies appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Annual Report on the EU’s Anti-Dumping, Anti-Subsidy and Safeguard activities and the Use of Trade Defence Instruments by Third Countries targeting the EU in 2020 /atp-research/annual-report-eu-safeguard/ Mon, 30 Aug 2021 15:13:13 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=30103 This 39th Report gives information on the EU’s anti-dumping, anti-subsidy and safeguard activities, as well as the trade defence activity of third countries against the EU in 2020, in line...

The post Annual Report on the EU’s Anti-Dumping, Anti-Subsidy and Safeguard activities and the Use of Trade Defence Instruments by Third Countries targeting the EU in 2020 appeared first on WITA.

]]>

This 39th Report gives information on the EU’s anti-dumping, anti-subsidy and safeguard activities, as well as the trade defence activity of third countries against the EU in 2020, in line with the Commission’s reporting obligations.

The European Union is committed to open rules-based trade, supported by the tools to defend European industry against unfair trade practices. The Commission ensures that where industries are harmed because of unfair practices, such as dumped and subsidised imports, they can rely on the EU’s trade defence instruments to provide an effective response.

Ensuring fair trade conditions for European producers also means dealing with trade defence actions taken by third countries against the EU, which reached their highest level in 2020.

While 2020 presented new and unique challenges in global trade, the Commission adapted and responded to these challenges and those posed by existing and new unfair trade practices and continued its enforcement of the EU’s trade defence instruments.

tradoc_159782

To read the full report from the European Commission, please click here.

The post Annual Report on the EU’s Anti-Dumping, Anti-Subsidy and Safeguard activities and the Use of Trade Defence Instruments by Third Countries targeting the EU in 2020 appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Reimagining Trade: Can Mutual Benefit be Restored? /atp-research/trade-mutual-benefit-restored/ Tue, 27 Jul 2021 23:10:39 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=29507 It is not an exaggeration to say that trade has transformed the world, especially during the latter half of the 20th century. While trade has not been an idyllic panacea,...

The post Reimagining Trade: Can Mutual Benefit be Restored? appeared first on WITA.

]]>
It is not an exaggeration to say that trade has transformed the world, especially during the latter half of the 20th century. While trade has not been an idyllic panacea, no other single factor has driven greater gains in global economic development and rising standards of living.

Today, the trade landscape looks like a battlefield. Protectionist policies are on the rise. Global trade governance has been derailed. The two largest economies in the world remain locked in the most significant trade war in 90 years, while smaller trade spats are breaking out across the globe. We are approaching an inflection point. If we hope to continue to derive transformative benefit in the decades to come, trade relationships will need to be reimagined.

In this essay, Hinrich Foundation Senior Research Fellow Stephen Olson notes that hardheaded pragmatism should point us towards a greater emphasis on broad based mutual benefit in our trade relationships. It would be counterproductive to have idealized expectations about a “Kumbaya moment”, but resorting to protectionism and the ‘blame game’ will do little to secure a sustainable future for workers, consumers, companies, and economies.

Reimagining trade can mutual benefit be restored - Hinrich Foundation white paper - Stephen Olson - July 2021

To read the full report from The Hinrich Foundation, please click here

The post Reimagining Trade: Can Mutual Benefit be Restored? appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Questioning Industrial Policy: Why Government Manufacturing Plans Are Ineffective and Unnecessary /atp-research/questioning-industrial-policy/ Wed, 16 Jun 2021 16:10:56 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=28359 In the wake of the COVID-19 pandemic and rising U.S.-China tensions, American policymakers have again embraced “industrial policy.” Both President Biden and his predecessor, as well as legislators from both...

The post Questioning Industrial Policy: Why Government Manufacturing Plans Are Ineffective and Unnecessary appeared first on WITA.

]]>

In the wake of the COVID-19 pandemic and rising U.S.-China tensions, American policymakers have again embraced “industrial policy.” Both President Biden and his predecessor, as well as legislators from both parties, have advocated a range of federal support for American manufacturers to fix perceived weaknesses in the U.S. economy and to counter China’s growing economic clout.

These and other industrial policy advocates, however, routinely leave unanswered important questions about U.S. industrial policy’s efficacy and necessity:

What is “Industrial Policy”? Advocates of “industrial policy” often fail to define the term, thus permitting them to ignore past failures and embrace false successes while preventing a legitimate assessment of industrial policies’ costs and benefits. Yet U.S. industrial policy’s history of debate and implementation establishes several requisite elements – elements that reveal most “industrial policy successes” not to be “industrial policy” at all.

What are the common obstacles to effective U.S. industrial policy? Several obstacles have prevented U.S. industrial policies from generating better outcomes than the market. This includes legislators’ and bureaucrats’ inability to “pick winners” and efficiently allocate public resources (Hayek’s “Knowledge Problem”); factors inherent in the U.S. political system (Public Choice Theory); lack of discipline regarding scope, duration, and budgetary costs; interaction with other government policies that distort the market at issue; and substantial unseen costs.

What “problem” will industrial policy solve? The most common problems purportedly solved by industrial policy proposals are less serious than advocates claim or unfixable via industrial policy. This includes allegations of widespread U.S. “deindustrialization” and a broader decline in American innovation; the disappearance of “good jobs”; the erosion of middle‐​class living standards; and the destruction of American communities.

Do other countries’ industrial policies demand U.S. industrial policy? The experiences of other countries generally cannot justify U.S. industrial policy because countries have different economic and political systems. Regardless, industrial policy successes abroad – for example, in Japan, Korea and Taiwan – are exaggerated. Also, China’s economic growth and industrial policies do not justify similar U.S. policies, considering the market‐​based reasons for China’s rise, the Chinese policies’ immense costs, and the systemic challenges that could derail China’s future growth and geopolitical influence.

These answers argue strongly against a new U.S. embrace of industrial policy. The United States undoubtedly faces economic and geopolitical challenges, including ones related to China, but the solution lies not in copying China’s top‐​down economic planning. Reality, in fact, argues much the opposite.

working-paper-63-updated

Scott Lincicome is a senior fellow in economic studies. He writes on international and domestic economic issues, including international trade; subsidies and industrial policy; manufacturing and global supply chains; and economic dynamism.

Huan Zhu is a research associate at the Cato Institute’s Herbert A. Stiefel Center for Trade Policy Studies, where her research primarily focuses on U.S.-China trade relations, World Trade Organization negotiations and disputes, as well as China’s trade and investment laws and policies.

To read the full report from the CATO Institute, please click here.

The post Questioning Industrial Policy: Why Government Manufacturing Plans Are Ineffective and Unnecessary appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Curbing State-Driven Trade Policies /atp-research/curbing-state-driven-trade-policies/ Mon, 13 Jul 2020 19:39:35 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=21775 Much attention has been focused on China’s unfair intellectual property practices and the imbalance in the U.S.-China trade relationship, but equally troubling are large-scale Chinese industrial subsidies, the behavior of...

The post Curbing State-Driven Trade Policies appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Much attention has been focused on China’s unfair intellectual property practices and the imbalance in the U.S.-China trade relationship, but equally troubling are large-scale Chinese industrial subsidies, the behavior of state-owned enterprises (SOEs), and in general, the oversized and opaque role of the Chinese state in the economy.

While the U.S-China phase one trade deal tackled some important sources of bilateral tension and aimed to boost Chinese purchases of U.S. goods and services, it was silent on industrial subsidies and related matters, leaving them for the next phase of negotiations, the fate of which is now in question. U.S. concerns on these matters are shared by other trading partners including the European Union (EU) and Japan. Yet despite widespread disapproval of such practices, building new global rules to combat subsidies has proven challenging. This is due to several factors, ranging from gridlock at the WTO, differences of views among like-minded countries on the required level of ambition, and uncertainty as to how best to approach the enormous complexities in China’s subsidies and related policies.

The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) has sought to unpack this complexity, conducting recent studies of Chinese subsidies in two key sectors: aluminum and semiconductors. Both studies illustrate how Chinese subsidies are not simple cash handouts from the state to protected firms so that they can sell at favorable and distorting prices. The OECD finds subsidies can take various forms, including downstream or upstream help that trickles up or down to the firm that’s intended to benefit. They can take the form of favorable equity or debt purchases or bonds provided at below-market rates. And with interconnected global value chains, subsidies can effectively be granted covertly, intended to benefit one firm that might be several links away along the chain.

In China, the problem is compounded by an opaque “party-state” structure that obscures not only the recipients of subsidies, but also the source. According to Mark Wu, a Harvard Law School professor who previously served as the Director for Intellectual Property in the Office of the U.S. Trade Representative, subsidies not only flow directly from government bodies in Beijing, but also indirectly through informal responses to directives — sometimes even left unsaid, but understood — from the Chinese Communist Party.

Against this backdrop, the Asia Society Policy Institute (ASPI) convened two roundtables in the fall of 2019 and the spring of 2020 to discuss how best to build a new rules-based infrastructure that might combat such subsidies and prevent trade-distorting results such as unfair competition, market access barriers, and, above all, overcapacity in global markets. Experts from the private sector, think tanks, governments, and academia weighed in with possible solutions, which included:

  1. Negotiating new rules in the WTO;
  2. Using the WTO dispute settlement system, despite its often-discussed flaws;
  3. Forming ad hoc rules-based approaches, where possible, like the U.S-EU-Japan trilateral initiative;
  4. Plurilateral negotiations conducted on a sector-by-sector basis;
  5. Forming coalitions of like-minded trading partners to establish an alternative model, much in the way that the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) was framed.

During the roundtables, most experts agreed that there is no silver bullet that solves the subsidy and related issues on its own. And most agree that, left unaddressed, the problem is likely to deepen. The COVID-19 pandemic might even exacerbate it by leading to more state involvement in economies around the world and making it hard to discipline Beijing’s practices. Recognizing all of these real challenges that the international trade community faces, the roundtables reached the following key conclusions:

  1. Transparency on the scope, level, and nature of industrial subsidies is vital;
  2. Efforts to publicize the ongoing work in these areas, particularly that being done by the OECD, should accelerate;
  3. Turning research into tangible new policies is a key step; and
  4. Persuading China to agree to updated rules will be necessary, given that China is a singular contributor to overcapacity.
Issue Brief_Curbing State-Driven Trade Policies

Wendy Cutler joined the Asia Society Policy Institute (ASPI) as Vice President in November 2015. She also serves as Managing Director of the Washington, D.C. Office.

To read the original brief, click here.

The post Curbing State-Driven Trade Policies appeared first on WITA.

]]>