bodog casino|Welcome Bonus_controls, nor would they http://www.wita.org/blog-topics/tax/ Mon, 19 Apr 2021 20:33:17 +0000 en-US hourly 1 https://wordpress.org/?v=6.6.1 /wp-content/uploads/2018/08/android-chrome-256x256-80x80.png bodog casino|Welcome Bonus_controls, nor would they http://www.wita.org/blog-topics/tax/ 32 32 bodog casino|Welcome Bonus_controls, nor would they /blogs/fertilizer-taxes-hurt-farmers/ Thu, 01 Apr 2021 20:26:55 +0000 /?post_type=blogs&p=27126 If the existing trade disputes with China were not bad enough for American farmers, now another trade action could hurt them. It will also likely hurt individuals and businesses throughout...

The post bodog casino|Welcome Bonus_ultimately increasing appeared first on bodog.

]]>
If the existing trade disputes with China were not bad enough for American farmers, now another trade action could hurt them. It will also likely hurt individuals and businesses throughout the food supply chain.

As a result of recent U.S. Department of Commerce and U.S. International Trade Commission findings, countervailing duties—taxes on imports that have been subsidized by the governments of the origin countries—will be imposed on Moroccan and Russian phosphate fertilizer imports.

These duties act in the same way as tariffs (taxes on imports) and are collected by U.S. Customs and Border Protection from American businesses importing the subjected goods.

The Department of Commerce and the International Trade Commission made their determinations after a single company, The Mosaic Co., filed petitions that claimed it was hurt by these imports.

Want to keep up with the 24/7 news cycle? Want to know the most important stories of the day for conservatives? Need news you can trust? Subscribe to The Daily Signal’s email newsletter. 

However, the harm imposed on Mosaic is questionable. Among many other factors, the company dominates phosphate fertilizer production in the United States and the domestic supply of this critical agricultural input is often unable to meet U.S. demand.

So, what will these duties mean?

First, it’s important to understand that foreign governments do not pay these duties, people do—in this case, U.S. farmers will bear the initial cost, although the extent of this is unclear.

In February, Bob Young, former chief economist for the American Farm Bureau Federation, estimated that the additional cost for corn, soybean, and wheat farmers alone could be $1–$1.5 billion for the coming crop year. 

Beyond costs, some commodity groups have argued that the duties could make it difficult for them to obtain adequate phosphate supplies and limit choices available to farmers.

It’s quite likely that the increased costs will be passed on throughout the food supply chain, ultimately increasing the prices that Americans pay for their food. As a result, these duties would be regressive, impacting low-income households the most; the lowest-income households spend a greater share of their disposable income on food (36%) compared to the highest-income households (8%).

All of this would be bad enough in “normal” times, but we are not in “normal” times. We are all living through a pandemic in which the health and economic impact is still being felt. It would only make the current bad situation worse to impose very questionable taxes on a critical agricultural input that will hinder the food supply chain.

Congress needs to correct this situation, otherwise these harmful duties will be in place for at least five years. At a minimum, legislators should review the situation and carefully consider whether Mosaic is being unfairly harmed by the phosphate fertilizer imports. They should also take into account the impact that the “fertilizer taxes” will have on farmers and American families, especially in light of the pandemic.

In doing so, legislators will almost certainly recognize that these “fertilizer taxes” are inappropriate. The only reasonable step would then be to remove the duties.

Agricultural trade is vital for farmers, ranchers, and American families. Farmers can import their bodog online casino inputs at competitive prices and differing qualities, and they can expand their sales by selling their excess supply abroad. Trade also provides a greater variety of food for Americans in the grocery store.

Congress and the Biden administration should move away from policies that increase government intervention that hinders agricultural trade. Americans need policymakers to increase freedom when it comes to agricultural trade. Removing these duties would be an important step in that direction.

After so much uncertainty, Americans deserve no less.  

To read the original blog from the Daily Signal, please click here 

The post bodog casino|Welcome Bonus_ultimately increasing appeared first on bodog.

]]>
bodog casino|Welcome Bonus_controls, nor would they /blogs/us-needs-co2-tax/ Fri, 13 Nov 2020 16:32:10 +0000 /?post_type=blogs&p=25026 The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change has made it clear: the world has until 2030 to implement “rapid and far-reaching” changes to our energy and infrastructure systems to avoid catastrophic levels...

The post bodog online casino|Welcome Bonus_emissions would apply appeared first on bodog.

]]>

The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change has made it clear: the world has until 2030 to implement “rapid and far-reaching” changes to our energy and infrastructure systems to avoid catastrophic levels of warming. Much of the attention is now focused on the best way to do so, with ideas ranging from local emissions goals, to more electric vehicles, to preventing food waste, to various ways to decrease the burning of carbon, with the majority of the effort aimed at reducing carbon emissions. With so little time left to make the far-reaching changes that must be made in the United States, policymakers need to concentrate on what is politically and practically achievable.  

Past U.S. initiatives have concentrated on tax credits and other support for renewable energy developments, cap-and-trade legislation that passed the House but not the Senate, regulatory actions including the Obama administration’s Clean Power Plan that was subsequently rolled back by the Trump administration, and more recently, a number of bills to impose a carbon tax (or more accurately a Green-House Gas (GHG) tax, as most of the bills include methane, nitrous oxide, hydrofluorocarbons, and sulfur hexafluoride) or other methods to place a price on GHG emissions. The pushback to all of these initiatives has centered on two claims: first, that imposing a price or restriction on GHG emissions will leave American companies, particularly in energy-intensive industries, at a competitive disadvantage to their counterparts in other countries that face no similar taxes or restrictions, and second, that imposing measures in the United States will only push energy-intensive companies offshore without forcing other countries to join the fight against climate change.

The only way to take effective and far-reaching action to combat climate change while also addressing these twin concerns is the imposition of a carbon tax with border adjustments imposing a comparable carbon tax on imports coming into the United States so that American companies are not disadvantaged, along with providing a rebate for carbon taxes paid in the United States when energy-intensive products are exported abroad. Acknowledgment that border-adjusted carbon taxes will accomplish the primary goal of reducing GHG emissions while leveling the playing field for American companies is coming from across the political spectrum.  As former Clinton administration Treasury Secretary Larry Summers put it: “The case bodog sportsbook review for carbon taxes has long been compelling.” And a group of prominent Republican leaders, led by former secretaries of both State and Treasury, James Baker and George Shultz, former Secretary of Treasury Hank Paulson, former chairmen of the Council of Economic Advisers Martin Feldstein and Gregory Mankiw, and business leaders have come together to put forward what they are calling the “conservative climate solution” of a carbon tax with border adjustments, with the revenues raised from the tax to be returned to the American people in the form of a monthly dividend.

When it comes to helping energy-intensive companies compete, border-adjusted carbon taxes are preferable because alternative regulatory approaches to limiting emissions would apply only in the United States to products made and sold in the United States. They would not shield American companies from low-priced imports from countries with no GHG controls, nor would they encourage other countries to adopt their own carbon controls. All of which begs the question of why, if border-adjusted carbon taxes are the best way to address climate change while creating a level playing field, they have not been adopted before now. The answer is many-fold but rests in part on the perceived difficulty—some would even say impossibility—of determining the amount of GHGs emitted in the production of a given product. Knowing that amount is vital to calculating both the amount of the carbon tax American producers would pay and the amount of any import charges or export rebates.  

The good news, however, is that much has changed since carbon taxes were initially considered. First, significant data has been collected both here in the United States and around the world.  U.S. companies have been required since 2007 to report GHG emissions from large sources. Industry associations and standards setting organizations both in the United States and around the world have agreed upon protocols and methodologies to allocate GHG emissions to various industrial processes. Fossil fuels have been measured and tested over long periods of time. Putting all of that altogether, scholars from Resources for the Future (RFF) have prepared extensive analyses demonstrating that GHG levels in products made both in the United States and abroad can be determined using well-established data and internationally agreed-upon standards. This new work is significant because it demonstrates that the “devil in the details” that previously plagued border-adjusted carbon tax efforts can be resolved using data and methodologies that can withstand scrutiny should there be any doubt or dispute over the numbers.

Second, the RFF work sets forth a practical and efficient approach to carbon taxes by limiting the number of U.S. taxpayers subject to the tax to those at the beginning of the carbon emissions cycle. The beauty of such a tax scheme is that it covers all emissions from the production and use of fossil fuels by applying the tax on coal, oil, and gas before they are combusted—that is at the wellhead for oil and gas or the mine mouth for coal—and then allowing the effects of the tax to flow through the economy, with everyone, particularly the most energy-intensive industries, paying the cost of the tax in the form of higher energy prices. The tax is easily administrable, in that the number of direct taxpayers would be limited to fossil fuel producers, electricity generators, and those that emit significant GHGs in the production of downstream products.

Third, by imposing an up-stream tax that can Bodog Poker be traced through the economy much like value-added taxes are done in many parts of the world, carbon tariffs can be shown to be consistent with World Trade Organization (WTO) rules that permit charges on imports that are equivalent to domestic taxes. Such carbon tariffs on imports of energy-intensive goods reflects a recognition that an upstream GHG tax could cause energy-intensive downstream industries to shift production to countries without comparable carbon pricing, thereby resulting in “leakage” of the very GHG emissions that the tax is designed to fully capture. Such production shifting to foreign markets would also disadvantage domestic manufacturers, their employees and the communities where they operate. Moreover, because carbon tariffs would be assessed depending on the amount of GHGs emitted in the production of goods in their home market, goods imported from dirty facilities in countries that do not regulate carbon would pay a higher import duty, thereby making it easier for more energy-efficient, cleaner American companies to compete.

Fourth, because border-adjusted carbon taxes can be rebated when American goods are exported, provided the data is in place to show that the amount of the rebate does not exceed the amount of taxes effectively paid in the United States, American companies will not be at a disadvantage when seeking to export their goods to foreign markets where their competitors are not paying a higher price for energy or GHG emissions. The RFF analysis provides the factual and analytical basis to make that required showing—that the export rebates do not exceed the amount of domestic taxes effectively paid, so providing a rebate does not result in an unfair promotion of American energy-intensive exports.

It is long past time for the United States to step up to the plate in reducing its own GHG emissions while encouraging and cajoling other countries to do likewise. Because such actions must be taken quickly, the fastest and most practical way to get to a resolution that strongly encourages reductions in GHG emissions at home, while discouraging carbon leakage and leveling the playing field for American companies competing abroad, is a border-adjusted carbon tax. Now that the data and the methodologies to do so are in hand, enacting such a tax system should be on Congress’ urgent priority list.

Creative Commons: Some rights reserved.

Jennifer A. Hillman is a senior fellow for trade and international political economy at the Council on Foreign Relations.

To read the original blog post, click here.

The post bodog online casino|Welcome Bonus_emissions would apply appeared first on bodog.

]]>
bodog casino|Welcome Bonus_controls, nor would they /blogs/companies-caught-taxes-trade-war/ Tue, 13 Oct 2020 14:02:18 +0000 /?post_type=blogs&p=23990 Taxes aren’t quite the certainty they once seemed to Benjamin Franklin. On Monday, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development said the new global rules it is developing could add $100 billion...

The post bodog casino|Welcome Bonus_countries proposing DSTs appeared first on bodog.

]]>
Taxes aren’t quite the certainty they once seemed to Benjamin Franklin.

On Monday, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development said the new global rules it is developing could add $100 billion a year to multinational companies’ tax bills. That might sound like an unappealing prospect for investors, but the OECD painted a bleaker alternative: a chaos of digital taxes and tariffs that could cut global output by 1%. This outcome would itself hit corporate earnings, even if the new levies didn’t.

The estimates were prepared for this month’s meeting of G20 finance ministers. The figures can be debated, but the basic trade-off is plausible: Politicians can agree to global tax changes or risk a trade war. Progress will have to wait until after November’s U.S. election, given that Washington’s participation is crucial. Unhelpfully, there isn’t a clear indication bodog sportsbook review of how either potential administration might proceed.

OECD officials had originally hoped for a deal by the end of this year, but are now aiming for summer 2021. If the negotiations fail, France and a number of other nations have committed to applying new digital service taxes, or DSTs, possibly prompting retaliatory U.S. tariffs. The resulting patchwork would “inevitably result in double taxation and even more uncertainty for businesses,” says Sarah Shive of the Information Technology Industry Council, a trade association.

Many countries, particularly in Europe, have long wanted U.S. tech companies to pay more corporate tax locally on services provided to their citizens. Silicon Valley typically pays low tax rates outside the U.S. as current rules focus on the location of plants, employees and other assets rather than sales. After agreeing to domestic tax changes in 2017, Washington showed renewed interest in a global overhaul, but seemed to get cold feet last December and suggested that the new rules be optional for U.S. companies.

That might sound like a nonstarter—who would opt in to higher taxes?—but big tech companies have said they wouldn’t mind paying more if it gave them certainty about their future bills. The choice to opt-in would give them a chance to follow through, though it isn’t clear that the countries proposing DSTs are willing to take them at their word and agree to an optional global overhaul.

Negotiations have settled on two revisions: changing taxing rights so that they don’t require a physical presence, and setting a minimum global tax.

The first change would reallocate about $100 billion of taxes from mostly low-tax jurisdictions to other countries with only a small overall increase, says the OECD. The minimum-tax provision is similar to the one introduced by the U.S. government in 2017, which was forecast to add $21 billion a year to U.S. multinationals’ tax bills by 2027. Creating a similar global rule would collect a further $80 billion from big multinationals based outside the U.S.

Companies might be willing to pay more for tax certainty, but they are unlikely to get it any time soon.

Rochelle Toplensky is a Heard on the Street columnist based in London, where she covers European banks and EU antitrust.

To read the original blog, click here.

The post bodog casino|Welcome Bonus_countries proposing DSTs appeared first on bodog.

]]>
bodog casino|Welcome Bonus_controls, nor would they /blogs/buy-america-rules-in-house-democrats-infrastructure-plan-would-cost-taxpayers/ Fri, 26 Jun 2020 20:29:00 +0000 /?post_type=blogs&p=21506 House Democrats recently released new details about their $1.5 trillion infrastructure plan, the Moving Forward Act (MFA). The mere size of the bill, given the record level of debt and...

The post bodog online casino|Welcome Bonus_House Democrats recently appeared first on bodog.

]]>
House Democrats recently released new details about their $1.5 trillion infrastructure plan, the Moving Forward Act (MFA). The mere size of the bill, given the record level of debt and deficits, should alarm taxpayers. Behind the price tag, though, is a protectionist agenda reflected in the bill’s enforcement and expansion of Buy America mandates. Although proponents of these rules claim they boost domestic production and create American jobs, there is no evidence that they would improve the economy overall. These Buy America provisions actually harm taxpayers because they require most federally-funded transportation projects to use expensive materials when there are more affordable alternatives available.

The Buy America Act was originally established within Section 165 of the Surface Transportation Assistance Act of 1982, and the provision was intended to give preference for the use of domestically produced materials on any transportation projects funded at least in part by the federal government. The term “Buy America” now refers to similar statutes and regulations that apply to federally-funded Bodog Poker transportation projects, including highways, public transportation, and intercity passenger rail. 

As the Congressional Research Service (CRS) notes, Buy America “generally requires that steel, iron, and manufactured products made primarily of steel or iron” used in federally-funded highway or transit projects that cost more than $1 million must be produced in the United States. This rule is already costing taxpayers money because of how expensive American steel and iron are compared to foreign steel and iron. 

What is alarming about the MFA is the expansion of the application of existing Buy America mandates. Section 1112 of the bill’s text adds “construction materials” to the materials covered by Buy America. As of now, the acquisition of iron and steel accounts for around 4.8 percent of the money spent on federally funded highway projects, which means that the requirement does not apply to 95.2 percent of the spending. However, if this term were to be added, the rule would apply to other materials, such as aggregates, cement, asphalt, etc. Applying the requirement to more infrastructure purchases would mean increased costs for taxpayers even more.

Fortunately, there are some limits to how much this provision can inflate costs. The Federal Highway Administration (FHWA) and the Federal Transit Administration (FTA) accept waivers based on public interest or the availability of domestic products. The provision would not apply if the Secretary of Transportation finds:

(1) that their application would be inconsistent with the public interest;

(2) that such materials and products are not produced in the United States in sufficient and reasonably available quantities and of a satisfactory quality; or

(3) that inclusion of domestic material will increase the cost of the overall project contract by more than 25 percent.

However, Section 1112 would restrict the waivers by requiring the Secretary to reevaluate any standing nationwide waivers every five years to decide whether those waivers remain necessary. Moreover, Section 2301 would also “close loopholes” that allow waived components and components exceeding 70 percent domestic content to receive credit for 100 percent domestic content. These new rules would decrease the number of waivers granted and incentivize higher domestic content—meaning higher costs for projects.

The claim that Buy America provisions benefit the economy has little to no evidence. The American steel industry is supposed to be one of the top industries that would benefit from Buy America, but its positive effect on the industry is scarce. According to CRS, the steel industry employment has declined from 260,000 jobs in 1990 to around 140,100 jobs in 2018, not because of foreign competition but because of higher productivity. If broader Buy America requirements were to increase annual demand for domestically manufactured steel by 1 million tons, it would only create around 1,000 jobs. 

Not only is Buy America’s purported benefit highly exaggerated, but its opportunity cost is also far greater than its advocates care to admit. The same study estimates that although eliminating Buy America requirements would take away 57,000 U.S. manufacturing jobs, it would also result in more than 300,000 new jobs in the economy. 

Bipartisan support regarding Buy America restrictions is growing. The Trump administration’s imposition of tariffs and the President’s executive order on buy American and hire American highlights his protectionist agenda. On the Democratic side, Rep. Conor Lamb (D-PA), who played a major bodog sportsbook review role in legislating the MFA, agrees with the President:

“The millions of Americans who have lost their jobs, and the millions more young people looking for a start in life in the middle of this pandemic, deserve to see us come together in support of this infrastructure bill. Building infrastructure is our most powerful tool to create jobs and improve the playing field for all businesses… It now falls to our generation to rebuild and improve upon this system for the twenty-first century.  This bill is an important down payment, and its focus on American jobs and American steel could not come at a better time.”

Meanwhile, Pennsylvania, the state that Lamb represents, has already experienced job loss and disruption of supply chains due to the tariffs on steel.

Lamb’s sentiment is typical among those who support protectionist policies, and they often suggest that buying American goods is not only economically beneficial but also virtuous. However, there is no reason to accept either claim. The empirical evidence does not show that Buy America rules benefit the U.S. economy, and there is nothing virtuous about shutting our country off to diverse global supply chains. What is certain is that Buy America rules would cost taxpayers, and it is time for Congress to have taxpayers’ interest as its priority and stop enforcing such requirements.

To view the original blog post at NTUF, please click here

 

The post bodog online casino|Welcome Bonus_House Democrats recently appeared first on bodog.

]]>