International Trade Archives - WITA /atp-research-topics/international-trade/ Fri, 27 Sep 2024 14:13:45 +0000 en-US hourly 1 https://wordpress.org/?v=6.6.1 /wp-content/uploads/2018/08/android-chrome-256x256-80x80.png International Trade Archives - WITA /atp-research-topics/international-trade/ 32 32 World Trade Report 2024 — Trade and Inclusiveness: How to Make Trade Work for All /atp-research/world-trade-report-2024/ Tue, 10 Sep 2024 13:44:30 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=50119 Over the past 30 years, the world has witnessed a period of income convergence, as the gap in income levels between economies has narrowed. Economic growth has improved living conditions...

The post World Trade Report 2024 — Trade and Inclusiveness: How to Make Trade Work for All appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Over the past 30 years, the world has witnessed a period of income convergence, as the gap in income levels between economies has narrowed. Economic growth has improved living conditions for many people around the world but not all individuals and economies have benefited equally from the changes brought about by more open trade. This year’s Report explores the interlinkages of trade and inclusiveness across and within economies, discussing how trade policies need to be complemented by domestic policies to make the benefits of trade more inclusive.

The Report underlines that diversifying global value chains, reducing trade costs through digitalization, and transitioning to a low-carbon economy can create new opportunities for low- and middle-income economies. Furthermore, when trade policies are complemented by domestic measures, such as labour, education and competition policies, the gains from trade can more easily flow to workers and consumers. Enhanced WTO cooperation with other international organizations can magnify their combined action to increase inclusiveness across and within economies.

WTO 2024 World Trade Report

To read the report as it was published on the World Trade Organization webpage, click here.

To read the full report, click here.

The post World Trade Report 2024 — Trade and Inclusiveness: How to Make Trade Work for All appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Ten Quick Wins for: Re-globalization and Resilience in Trade /atp-research/ten-quick-wins/ Mon, 09 Sep 2024 20:53:15 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=50250 Foreword The year 2024 marks a global election cycle with over 80 countries, representing more than half of the world’s population casting their votes. In these uncertain times, the world...

The post Ten Quick Wins for: Re-globalization and Resilience in Trade appeared first on WITA.

]]>

Foreword

The year 2024 marks a global election cycle with over 80 countries, representing more than half of the world’s population casting their votes. In these uncertain times, the world finds itself confronted by a state of “polycrisis”—a complex web of interconnected global challenges that transcends borders. Geopolitics and international trade have a critical role to play in driving solutions to these crises. 

As many countries continue to navigate the aftermath of the COVID-19 pandemic, the world contends with other pressing issues such as the increasing urgency of tackling climate change and addressing the fragmentation of traditional geopolitical alliances. As nations confront various stressors, including ongoing conflicts in several regions around the world, these interconnected issues have heightened uncertainties and undermined the previously robust support for open trade.

Ten Quick Wins for: Re-globalization and Resilience in Trade

Quick Win No. 1

In the past three decades, the world has enjoyed numerous benefits of trade liberalization. For example, in the first 25 years since the establishment of the WTO average tariffs dropped from 10.5% to 6.4%, and the value of global trade nearly quadrupled. The emergence of a global supply chain seamlessly weaved goods and services from various corners of the world into products ready for consumers’ hands. However, disruptions in recent years, such as the COVID-19 pandemic, climate-change-related natural disasters, and geopolitical events, have exposed significant risks in the global supply chain model. These disruptions have propelled businesses to diversify their supply chains in order to mitigate disruption risks. This means increasing sourcing opportunities from a diverse geographical footprint.

Quick Win No. 2

Trade policy can significantly leverage re-globalization to achieve a net-zero world, but it is crucial to ensure these measures include developing countries, particularly the most vulnerable and marginalized. Climate science advocates for enhanced efforts to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions and move towards a sustainable energy future, as underscored by the 2023 Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) Synthesis Report. Agreements like the 2015 Paris Agreement and the 2021 Glasgow Climate Pact have set ambitious targets for net-zero carbon dioxide emissions by mid-century. However, developing countries often lack the financial resources, technological advancements, and institutional capacity to meet these targets. This risks their exclusion from the benefits of global climate initiatives such as carbon markets and clean energy transitions.

Quick Win No. 3

Workers are the backbone of international trade. They provide global services, the labor for tradable goods, and the means to ship exports and imports. Despite their unique importance to trade, not all workers are treated equally, and many groups are excluded from the design, implementation, and enforcement of trade policies. Countries should offer a seat at the trade policy table not only to advantaged trade union representatives but also to vulnerable workers who lack union representation.

Quick Win No. 4

The world is on the cusp of a transformative shift as the growth of clean energy and digital technologies propel humanity toward a minerals-based economy. This transformation holds the promise of a more sustainable and interconnected future, but it will also be highly material intensive. Meeting the burgeoning demand for these materials will necessitate an unprecedented expansion of mining activities. Experts estimate that the demand for lithium-ion batteries alone could require more than 300 new mines by 2035. Emerging green technologies will further accelerate demand for critical minerals needed for the generation and transmission of more renewable energy.

Quick Win No. 5

Cross-border data flows are crucial for trade and digital economy innovation. The rapid advancement and adoption of artificial intelligence (AI) further highlights the need to ensure that data flows freely, safely, and securely across borders. However, diverse and sometimes irreconcilable policy interests of WTO members have fueled the lack of agreement on vital issues, such as data governance, and slimmed down the negotiation agenda within the WTO’s Joint Statement Initiative on Electronic Commerce (E-Commerce JSI). These developments reflect ongoing concerns about shrinking policy space, privacy, national security, and data sovereignty, which can lead to regulatory fragmentation and restrictions on data flows. While AI is not currently included in the E-Commerce JSI, rapid developments in AI governance outside the WTO indicate the potential for further fragmentation. We propose a pragmatic approach focused on inclusivity through regulatory interoperability and technical harmonization, where certification frameworks and technical standards play a key role.

Quick Win No. 6

The WTO dispute settlement system is vital for enforcing WTO rules and providing security and predictability to the multilateral trading system. While the system has been by and large effective over the past 30 years, its practical application over time has made clear that some aspects need improvement or clarification. Accumulated dissatisfaction of some WTO members over certain features of the system, especially related to appellate review, led to a deadlock in the appointment of Appellate Body members to replace those whose terms of office had expired. This situation came to a head in December 2019, when the Appellate Body became non-functional due to a lack of quorum.

Quick Win No. 7

Responding to the perception that aspects of international trade create economic security risks, some WTO members have implemented unilateral, trade-inhibiting measures that lack clear endpoints. Members may justify violations of trade rules by invoking the WTO security exceptions, provided all requirements are met. However, security exceptions are not a long-term solution for persistent, unpredictable challenges and may even preclude multilateral approaches to anticipate and mitigate economic security risks. It is time to view security as more than an exception to WTO rules and principles. Members should build a new mechanism for economic security issues using the WTO’s safeguards procedures as a model.

Quick Win No. 8

Redirecting investment flows to developing and least-developed economies is one of the key challenges to overcome when thinking about a new paradigm for globalization and building resilience in trade. The Joint Initiative on Investment Facilitation for Development, launched by some WTO members in December 2017, aimed to address trade barriers that impede and restrict investment processes between countries. Although the conclusion of the negotiations on the Investment Facilitation for Development (IFD) Agreement was announced in February 2024, the Agreement was not incorporated into Annex 4 of the Marrakesh Agreement during the 13th WTO Ministerial Conference (MC13). Establishing these rules at the multilateral level is crucial to creating a cohesive and inclusive global investment environment, which will enhance the participation of developing and least-developed WTO members in global investment.

Quick Win No. 9

Across the globe, governments are increasingly confronting the urgent challenge of combating climate change. The green transition is essential to tackle this challenge and necessitates wide scale innovation and dissemination of advanced clean technologies. While the clean tech boom is underway, many developing countries are struggling to keep pace. The WTO is uniquely positioned to facilitate technology transfer by leveraging its existing frameworks and enhancing international cooperation with existing initiatives, such as those of the UNFCCC.

Quick Win No. 10

For decades, development finance has played a critical role in supporting financial resilience in developing countries. However, even countries that are striving to increase their economic strength remain vulnerable to external macroeconomic shocks and geopolitical uncertainties. One way development finance can help shield developing economies from shocks and drive inclusive growth is by championing the adoption of digital payments—including open and competitive payments markets and public-private partnerships.

TradeExperettes_10+Quick+Wins+for+Re-globalization+and++Resilience+in+Trade+FINAL-compressed
 
To read the report as it was published on the TradeExperettes webpage, click here.
 
To read the full report, click here.

The post Ten Quick Wins for: Re-globalization and Resilience in Trade appeared first on WITA.

]]>
The EU’s Critical Raw Materials Strategy: Engaging with the World to Achieve Self-Sufficiency /atp-research/eus-materials-strategy/ Sun, 01 Sep 2024 19:41:46 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=49888 The tussle over critical raw materials Critical raw materials (CRMs) are the bedrock of the world’s renewable energy systems. As economies around the world are committing to decarbonization, demand for critical...

The post The EU’s Critical Raw Materials Strategy: Engaging with the World to Achieve Self-Sufficiency appeared first on WITA.

]]>
The tussle over critical raw materials

Critical raw materials (CRMs) are the bedrock of the world’s renewable energy systems. As economies around the world are committing to decarbonization, demand for critical minerals—the key components of clean technologies powering the green transition—is swiftly outpacing supply: the International Energy Agency (IEA) forecasts that the global energy sector’s requirements for energy transition minerals could quadruple by 2040. Confronted with growing competition for control over critical mineral supply chains, governments worldwide have implemented new policies, marshaled funding, and forged alliances to protect their access to these essential materials.

Although concerns over CRM supplies were raised as early as 2008, supply chain insecurities exposed during the Covid-19 pandemic and the challenges of reducing the EU’s energy dependencies in the aftermath of Russia’s invasion of Ukraine catapulted the issue of reliable access to energy transition minerals to the top of the EU’s political agenda.

The need to reduce dependencies on the EU’s access to CRMs figured prominently in Ursula von der Leyens political guidelines which were presented to the European Parliament on July 18th. She underscored the need to create a secondary market for CRMs, but also underlined that the EU need to diversify its supply and aggregate its demand as well as a need to boost European investment in the sector.

While we are still awaiting Mario Draghi’s report on the EU’s competitiveness, access to CRMs are also expected to be a central theme here. Speaking on April 16, 2024, Mario Draghi, the former president of the European Central Bank, thematized the urgency of securing Europe’s strategic autonomy in critical raw materials value chains. In a world where global superpowers such as the United States and China are turning to protectionist policies to shore up their CRM supply, the EU, Draghi underlined, needs “a comprehensive strategy covering all stages of the critical mineral supply chain.” 

The Critical Raw Materials Act (CRMA), which entered into force on May 23 of this year, is the EU’s initial attempt to build such a strategic approach. The regulation focuses on measures the EU can implement domestically to increase its raw materials resilience: ramping up extraction at home, increasing circularity and recycling efforts, and fostering innovation in alternative technologies. By 2030, 10% of all the EU’s annual consumption of strategic raw materials is to be extracted domestically and 40% is to be processed within the EU. At least 15% of the EU’s annual consumption is to come from recycled sources. According to observers, these targets set by the EU are widely ambitious and will most likely not be achieved by 2030.

The EU, however, will never be entirely self-sufficient in supplying the critical raw materials it requires and will always rely on CRM imports. Even in the best-case scenario where the CRMA’s goals are reached, 90% of the extraction and 60% of the processing of the EU’s yearly requirements will still occur overseas. Currently, geospatial concentration of supply chains leaves Europe’s critical raw material supply—and with it, Europe’s climate ambitions—vulnerable to supply disruptions, external shocks, and the tactics of trade wars.

For a handful of CRMs, the EU is almost solely dependent on a small number of third countries. For example, 98% of the EU’s supply of borate comes from Turkey and 63% of the world’s cobalt is extracted in the Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC). China’s stranglehold over global CRM extraction and, especially, refinement is a serious concern. For example, 100% of the rare earth elements used in permanent magnets are refined there. As the EU and US attempt to loosen China’s grip on CRM value chains, China is becoming more and more assertive in using its dominant position to defend its control of the market. In 2020, China ranked as the country with the most export restrictions on minerals, and, in 2023, introduced additional restrictions for graphite and for rare-earth mineral processing technology. Even the EU’s recently announced plans to impose tariffs on electric vehicles produced in China—an attempt to curb Chinese dominance at the downstream end of the critical mineral value chain—provoked Chinese authorities to open anti-dumping probes into European pork and French spirits in what was widely seen as a retaliatory response.

To secure a reliable CRM supply, the EU must reduce these dependencies. Thus, the CRMA establishes that, by 2030, not more than 65% of the EU’s annual consumption of each strategic raw material at any stage of the value chain is to be sourced from a single third country. This brief, which builds on Tænketanken EUROPA’s previous works, seeks to unpack the strategies deployed by the EU in pursuit of this diversification target. 

Why trade is not enough

There is an ongoing political discussion both within the Commission, but also among Member States, as to whether the EU can secure its critical mineral supply chains through mere import diversification or whether the EU also needs to build up industrial capacity in third countries. So far, the EU has been pursuing strategies along both these vectors, completing trade and investment agreements to increase its network of preferred trading partners and signing strategic partnerships to create investment opportunities overseas.

Industry forecaster, Benchmark Minerals, estimates that at least 384 new graphite, lithium, nickel, and cobalt mines will have to be opened by 2035 to meet global demand for electric vehicle battery materials alone. To secure true stability of supply, the EU thus cannot rely solely on increasing its number of trading partners but must be proactive in ensuring European engagement in supply chains on competitive terms.

Since mining and processing are capital intensive processes, accompanied by a slew of associated environmental and business risks, attracting investment in mineral projects poses a challenge the EU must overcome. The EU must think beyond its current strategies, which though feasible are not sufficiently innovative, to develop tools that will both incentivize and protect European stakeholder involvement.

Reducing dependencies through development: The EU’s Strategic Partnerships

The EU’s raw materials strategy has emphasized the creation of Strategic Partnerships on Raw Materials Value Chains, which are formalized in memoranda of understanding (MoUs) and pledge to facilitate investment in CRM value chains abroad. The EU has forged 13 such agreements with mineral-rich countries outside of the Union since 2017, with more agreements in the pipeline.

The partnerships aim to promote economic development in cooperating countries in mineral extraction, processing, and related infrastructure, scaling up global CRM output. Being non-legally binding, the MoUs are practical: they are easy to set up, quick to push through the internal machinery of the EU, and they satisfy a political appetite for official statements of cooperation. They are followed by more concrete, though still not legally binding, roadmaps identifying projects and laying out a step-by-step approach to achieving the goals of the partnership, which the EU and its partners agree to design within six months of the Strategic Partnership’s signing.

By opening up opportunities for EU investors to establish a foothold in third countries, the strategic partnerships constitute a means of establishing a European presence in global CRM supply chains. In the MoUs, the EU promises prioritized funding for projects through the EU Global Gateway, the EU’s foreign investment policy initiated in 2021. Global Gateway has earmarked a total of €300 billion to clean energy and infrastructure projects worldwide. Deploying Global Gateway funds and a Team Europe approach, under which the EU pools resources from the EU, Member States, and other actors such as development finance institutions and the European Investment Bank, the EU hopes to stimulate private sector investment in partnering countries. However, investors will need more concrete incentives than the Partnerships alone, not least because the Strategic Partnerships, as non-binding compacts, do not create the clear and enforceable legal guarantees necessary to support investments.

Reducing dependencies through trade policy: Understanding the EU’s exclusive competence FTAs

In addition to forming Strategic Partnerships, the EU has doubled down on efforts to bring pending trade agreements with resource-rich countries across the finish line, in a move to diversify its critical mineral supply by increasing trade privileges in CRM markets worldwide. While FTAs are broad arrangements that cover relations across a range of economic sectors, critical raw materials can be a driving force behind these agreements. All new EU trade agreements since 2015 have contained a dedicated chapter on Energy and Raw Materials.

Trade agreements have limited power to stimulate imports of critical raw materials into the EU because there is little scope for country-specific tariff reductions on CRMs. 92% of EU CRM imports do not pay import duties, whether because of tariffs set at zero or trade agreements already in force. The remaining CRM imports are covered by a tariff ranging from 2-7% for unprocessed and 3-9% for processed goods. As such, there is little scope for significant further reduction. However, the EU’s FTAs can be understood as reflecting a shift away from traditional trade liberalization methods and towards increasing opportunities for EU companies in sourcing SRMs overseas, much like the Strategic Partnerships, although FTAs are legally binding accords.

However, trade agreements might help restrict protectionist CRM policies implemented by mineral exporting countries. Such measures pose a worrying barrier to trade in critical minerals. In newly developed FTA provisions, the EU has included additional rules which aim to address defensive CRM trade strategies adopted by resource-rich countries and to close gaps in existing WTO regulations. Recent FTAs have also sought to open foreign markets to EU investors in the extractive industries of FTA partners, for example by securing preferential access for EU investors to trading opportunities and ensuring non-discriminatory procedures in the authorization of exploration and production licenses. 

Since 2017, the EU has crafted more agile FTAs—slimmed down agreements designed to fall under exclusive EU competence which can enter into force with only the consent of the EU Council and European Parliament. In this way, the EU has managed to accelerate the exhaustive ratification procedure associated with traditional trade agreements. However, the EU’s newest trade agreements, including the deals with mineral-rich Chile, New Zealand, and Vietnam, are unable to secure full protection and security for EU investors once they are operating in foreign markets: because investment protection counts as an area of shared competence, these FTAs must leave out provisions protecting EU investors against the expropriation of their investments.

Though offering a promising way of expediting FTA ratification, the inability of exclusive competence FTAs to secure investment protection makes these agreements weak supports for the Strategic Partnerships’ investment push. The EU’s current Strategic Partners are predominantly countries where no trade agreement with investor protection articles is in force, whether because negotiations have been on hold, as is the case in the DRC and Zambia, or because ratification is embattled, as is the case with the MERCOSUR country, Argentina.

Investment protection: The missing piece in the EU’s strategy

Neither exclusive EU competence FTAs nor Strategic Partnerships include robust, legal-binding, investment safeguarding measures, which, though controversial, can be crucial prerequisites for investor engagement. It is only with fully-fledged, shared competence trade and investment agreements that the EU has the ability to ensure legally binding investment protection mechanisms, including the shielding of EU investments against discriminatory judicial and administrative procedures and the safeguarding of investors against expropriation or nationalization of their investments. These rules have bite: Investor State Dispute Settlement (ISDS) provisions grant EU investors standing to sue the EU’s trading partners directly. Remedies include financial compensation or restitution of expropriated property. Due to investment risks in many of the EU’s partnering countries, investment protection provides the stability essential for the kind of investment in raw materials value chains that the EU hopes to foster. ISDS procedures, however, are increasingly coming under fire for enabling private companies to sue governments when climate policies or local opposition affects their profits. Should the EU’s trading partners grant EU investors the right to ISDS procedures, they would expose themselves to substantial risk of lawsuits and weaken their leverage to take further measures to protect the environment, as well as protected and indigenous land. As EU-level investor protection measures will not materialize soon, mechanisms for de-risking investment will have to be installed on a project level basis, including guarantees from the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency (MIGA) of the World Bank, from national export credit agencies, or the private political risk insurance market

Recommended flanking measures

Import diversification alone is not enough to ensure stable and resilient supply of critical raw materials, foreign—and especially Chinese industry—is already far too involved for diversification to be a potent strategy. Chinese mining companies have already made conspicuous acquisitions in mining infrastructure abroad, spending $10 billion in the first half of 2023 alone. Chinese enterprise has established significant control over cobalt and copper mining in the DRC and nickel mining in Indonesia and has its sights set on South America’s lithium triangle.

European mining industry must therefore insert itself in third countries in order to bolster a resilient supply of CRMs. Strategic Partnerships and the EU’s excusive competence trade agreements are feasible tools, albeit weak in that they lack investor protection and dispute settlement measures. As such, the EU must pursue a broad range of flanking measures toinsert European stakeholders in global CRM production, offering secure measures that can counterbalance the lack of investment protection treaties. Relying, as it does, on private investments to achieve the CRMA’s diversification goals, the EU must develop strong incentives for European investors to move to risky markets and build a European mining industry there.

Firstly, the EU should look to motivate Member States to direct national funding towards projects in the Strategic Partnership countries and coordinate the diplomatic efforts of individual Member States. France has signed bilateral agreements on raw materials with Canada and Australia. Germany has been conducting diplomatic visits to strengthen its relationships with mineral-rich countries around the world and has formed partnerships with Mongolia, Kazakhstan, and Peru, among others. Germany, Italy, and France have all announced national Raw Materials Funds amounting to €2.5 in total of public funds, which will focus on financing domestic mining operations.

In addition to nudging national investments towards Strategic Partnership countries, the EU can stimulate European companies to initiate CRM production through purchasing agreements, which are long-term contracts that establish foresight on the offtake of products. The EU has already made use of purchasing agreements to supply vaccines (APAs) and in the power sector (PPAs) and is considering their application to the defense sector. 

The EU can also ensure foresight through contracts for difference (CfDs), which fix a floor price for a set number of years and a set quantity. Such measure could be used to set a European floor price for CRMs and thus guard against price dumping. However, the EU would need both to use its budget as a guarantee and to establish a fund dedicated to subsidizing producers. There is a risk related to such tools, as technological innovation might make certain CRMs redundant more rapidly than currently expected.

Nudging investment towards projects that are not yet bankable remains a key challenge. In July 2023, the EU made all stages of the CRM value chain eligible for European Investment Bank financing. The EU could further explore the expansion of existing EU programs, for example the Just Transition Fund, Horizon Europe, or the Connecting Europe Facility program, to co-finance projects either aimed at developing the European mining industry, or to co-finance projects in resource rich countries with which the EU has strategic partnerships. The EU should also consider lowering the eligibility threshold for CRM extraction projects to support their early-stage development and encourage financial aid from Member States for these initial stages.

Currently, the EU’s development finance institutions and Global Gateway program have no means for excluding investment from the EU’s geopolitical competitors in countries where the EU has a Strategic Partnership in place. There is an on-going discussion within the Commission—also beyond the fields of CRMs—as to whether the EU’s public procurement procedures can be adapted to shield against non-EU investment, for example by including resilience criteria in the evaluation of bidders, or by making EU support for European firms reliant on them investing in supply chain resilience.

A culture shift is needed to conceptualize EU-level development aid, with conditions that receiving countries should privilege European interests in developing their CRM sectors. Work must continue in the Commission to determine how existing competition rules (including public procurement) which are currently focused on the internal market can be used or adapted to ensure that the European mining industry’s growth overseas and the EU’s development aid objectives are not hobbled by competition from non-EU investors.

The EU can also apply taxonomy certification to CRMs to incentivize “green” investments. In January, German group TÜV NORD launched its “CERA 4in1” four step ESG-compliance certification standard for minerals along the entire value chain, from raw material to manufactured product. This EU-funded project is an example of a certification scheme that could be beneficial to the EU in designing its own taxonomy. Building on a taxonomy certification the EU could consider establishing a “green” content requirement in the up-stream value chain including finished manufactured product using CRMs. 

Going further, the EU could establish a European content requirement for the CRM value chain. Although a tantalizing means for loosening the control of Europe’s geopolitical competitors, this measure cannot be deployed before the EU has built up a sufficient European CRM supply.

Presently, there is limited CRM export from Europe, but in the future the EU could impose export restrictions, such as export taxes, on the export of CRMs processed or extracted in the EU. These measures would incentivize European processing and distribution but would not increase the EU’s access to raw material supply chains in third countries. The EU could also build its domestic processing capacity through FDI screening.

Both export control and FDI screening are national competences, although attempts have been made to harmonize the EU Member States’ approach. Current EU FDI regulation already flags critical infrastructure, critical technologies, and the supply of critical inputs, such as energy or raw materials as factors that are likely to affect security or public order. Future revisions of the EU’s FDI Screening Regulation could opt to include firmer obligations for EU Member States in screening for ESG standards in these critical areas. However, these measures do not apply to guarding against foreign direct investment threats in foreign countries, with which the EU has strategic partnerships and its own investment interests. 

Currently, there exist differences between Member State investment insurance products, including discrepancies in pricing, in coverage percentage, and in the extent of diplomatic leverage attached to the guarantees. The EU must continue working towards a comprehensive EU export credit strategy and convene the European credit agencies, which are currently governed under national laws, and the relevant development finance institutions to create a more harmonized approach, collaborate on larger packages, and condition their investments to promote EU enterprise. 

To reach stable and resilient supplies of CRMs, the EU must also increase its attractiveness as a partner for resource-rich countries and work to fend off increased competition in overseas markets. The EU can increase its bargaining power by strengthening its leverage to purchase unrefined or processed CRMs through joint procurement mechanisms. Under joint procurement processes, EU Member States sign up on a voluntary basis to combine purchasing power. The EU’s joint procurement mechanism proved its effectiveness during the Covid-19 pandemic in securing affordable medical supplies. In May, the Commission announced that it was beginning to outline plans for joint purchases of approximately 30 materials, using as a blueprint the scheme of joint gas purchases launched in 2022.

The protectionist instincts of many of these measures represent a radical shift in the EU’s modus operandi as they run counter to the logic of rule-bound free trade. For example,the imposition of export controls would require the EU to back-track significantly on its previous stance, since the EU has historically used FTAs and WTO accession agreements to prevent exactly such strategies. If the EU is serious about securing its CRM supply, however, it will need to reconsider its long-held stance on economic protectionism.

Conclusion

The EU’s ambitions regarding its overseas supply of Critical Raw Materials will be slow in coming to fruition. The EU’s strategic partnerships are an initial step in a long-term engagement spanning years, as mines can take decades from the first exploration to active production and investments in facilities overseas can take years to make returns. Those politicians who put critical raw materials on the ticket will not necessarily able to show concrete successes within one political cycle. 

Nevertheless, critical raw materials and the EU’s strategic dependencies have rightly risen on the EU’s agenda since negotiations for the current long-term budget (MFF) for 2021-2027 began in 2018. The proposal for the next MFF is expected to be tabled during the Danish EU presidency in the second half of 2025. Denmark should push for an overarching critical raw materials framework with a coherent, strong, and pragmatic stance on financing development in the critical raw materials sector, at home and overseas. This framework should include both dedicated EU funding for exploration, extraction, and processing within and outside of the Union as well as ambitious tools aimed at shielding European endeavors and ensuring foresight on CRM prices and offtake.

The EU’s Critical Raw Materials Strategy_ Engaging with the World to Achieve Self-Sufficiency

To read the analysis as it was published on the Tænketanken Europa webpage, click here.

To read the full analysis PDF, click here.

The post The EU’s Critical Raw Materials Strategy: Engaging with the World to Achieve Self-Sufficiency appeared first on WITA.

]]>
How Trade Agreements Have Enhanced the Freedom and Prosperity of Americans /atp-research/trade-freedom-and-prosperity/ Tue, 27 Aug 2024 20:42:26 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=50245 An essential part of America’s turning away from protectionism since the Great Depression has been the signing of free trade agreements (FTAs) with other nations. Those agreements, while imperfect, have...

The post How Trade Agreements Have Enhanced the Freedom and Prosperity of Americans appeared first on WITA.

]]>

An essential part of America’s turning away from protectionism since the Great Depression has been the signing of free trade agreements (FTAs) with other nations. Those agreements, while imperfect, have led to lower tariffs and other barriers to trade, in the United States and abroad. They also have provided incentives for compliance through dispute settlement while discouraging mutually damaging trade wars. Although the impact of trade agreements has often been exaggerated by both their advocates and opponents, decades of experience and economic analysis confirm that the benefits for most Americans have been positive. The United States today is a richer and freer nation, and the world is a more hospitable place for economic activity because of those trade agreements.

The most straightforward and preferable path to trade liberalization for any country is the unilateral reduction of trade barriers without regard for other countries’ trade policies. Unilateral liberalization allows a country to realize the gains from openness—mainly lower prices for consumers, lower-cost inputs for businesses, and a more favorable exchange rate for exporters—without the need for complicated negotiations with other countries. Many nations have followed this route with success, from Great Britain in the mid–19th century to China and India and other emerging economies since the 1980s. As discussed in a separate Defending Globalization essay, however, unilateral liberalization is politically difficult, so governments have turned to reciprocal trade agreements, which offer reduced trade barriers at home in exchange for similar liberalization among participating governments abroad. The best approach to trade agreement liberalization is multilateral—the lowering of barriers to goods, services, and investment in a nondiscriminatory way by almost all countries through such forums as the World Trade Organization (WTO). A next-best option is bilateral and regional FTAs among two or several governments, respectively.

The United States is a partner in bilateral and regional FTAs with 20 other nations, including such major trading partners as Canada, Mexico, South Korea, Singapore, and Australia. The United States was a founding member of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade after World War II and is a member of its successor institution, the WTO, a multilateral agreement with 165 other countries that covers 98 percent of world trade. The United States is also party to narrower bilateral investment treaties with about 40 other nations that protect American investment assets abroad.

The 20 bilateral and regional FTAs that the United States has signed have virtually eliminated tariffs on US exports to those countries. Those FTAs have achieved what even trade populists claim as a goal: reciprocal tariff rate reductions. By definition, FTAs set virtually all tariffs between the signatory nations at zero. The reductions, as well as liberalizing components (restrictions on nontariff barriers, services, and investment disciplines, for example), can be phased in over time, and a few politically sensitive sectors can be excluded, but substantially all trade under the 20 FTAs that the United States has signed occurs duty-free.

A Brief History of US Trade Agreements

To better understand why trade agreements have become so important to US trade policy, we need to step back to the early 1930s, to the passage of the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act and the beginning of the Great Depression.

In response to low prices in the farm sector, Congress began drafting the Trade Act of 1930, better known as the Smoot–Hawley tariffs after its sponsors Rep. Willis C. Hawley and Sen. Reed Smoot. The bill quickly morphed from raising agricultural tariffs to hiking tariffs on thousands of other products—some of which were not even produced in the United States—as it moved through Congress. The result of this congressional logrolling was the largest tariff increase in US history, signed by President Herbert Hoover in June 1930.

The consequences of the unilateral tariff hike were a disaster. Instead of saving jobs and promoting industry, the tariffs accelerated the US economy’s slide into depression. Major US trading partners retaliated with tariffs of their own aimed at US exports. Global trade dropped dramatically. By 1933, real US gross domestic product had dropped by a third, and the unemployment rate hit 25 percent. Republicans lost the White House and control of Congress in 1932 as Franklin Roosevelt swept into office in a landslide.

Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934

America’s historic turn away from protectionism began with the passage of the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act (RTAA) in 1934. The bill gave the administration authority to negotiate agreements with other nations to reduce tariffs by up to 50 percent. Tariff reductions negotiated with one country were automatically applied to imports from all other countries that treated US trade on a nondiscriminatory, or “most-favored nation,” basis. By 1940, the United States had effectively reversed the Smoot–Hawley tariffs through agreements done pursuant to the RTAA.

The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade

At the end of World War II, the United States joined with noncommunist, “free world” trading partners to establish the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). Beginning in 1947 and under successive rounds, the US president under RTAA authority negotiated multilateral agreements with an expanding club of countries that significantly reduced tariffs in the United States and around the world. Global trade expanded sharply, as did the post-war economic expansion. The initial Geneva Round in the GATT committed its members to reciprocity, unconditional most-favored nation treatment, and opposition to quantitative restrictions on trade. The GATT also served a vital foreign-policy role by assisting Western Europe’s recovery after the devastation of World War II. It also knit NATO allies closer together economically during the Cold War in the face of the military threat from the Soviet Union.

The Carter administration negotiated the Tokyo Round Agreement in 1979, which resulted in average tariff reductions of 34 percent by the United States, the European Economic Community, and Japan. For the first time in the GATT, the round curbed the use (and abuse) of nontariff barriers in government procurement, technical barriers to trade, subsidies and countervailing duties, customs valuation, import licensing procedures, and anti-dumping.

The Uruguay Round and the WTO

The GATT process culminated in the Uruguay Round Agreement of 1994, which further reduced global tariffs and established the WTO to administer the agreement and resolve disputes. Like the Tokyo Round, the Uruguay Round reduced global tariffs by an average of one-third. It phased out the Multi-Fiber Arrangement, a system of rich-country quotas on imports of clothing and textiles dating back to 1974. “Voluntary” export-restraint agreements were banned, requiring nations to rely on existing anti-dumping and safeguard laws to address politically sensitive imports. Farm subsidies were reduced and constrained. For the first time, the round established rules governing the treatment of foreign investment, intellectual property, trade in services, and technical issues in trade (such as abusing sanitary and phytosanitary measures to restrict imports). The agreement also established a more robust dispute settlement mechanism to encourage better compliance, a key goal of US negotiators.

The Uruguay Round Agreement achieved major US objectives. It reduced global barriers to US exports of goods and services and established the “rule of law” in global trade and commerce. For the export-oriented sector of US agriculture, the agreement created a more open and market-friendly global market. For American consumers, the Multi-Fiber Arrangement’s abolition allowed for more trade in clothing, delivering lower prices to millions of American households, especially lower-income families, while helping to reduce poverty domestically as well as abroad.

NAFTA and Other Regional and Bilateral Agreements

Beginning in the 1980s, the US government signed a series of regional and bilateral trade agreements with specific trading partners. As noted, those agreements have eliminated virtually all tariffs on trade between these partners, liberalized trade in services, and created rules for intellectual property and direct investment that are more stringent than those in the WTO agreements. The agreements have been a bipartisan project, negotiated by Republican and Democratic presidents alike and approved with bipartisan majorities by Congress.

The most important and controversial of those FTAs has been the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) between the United States, Canada, and Mexico. The agreement first went into effect in 1994 and was renegotiated by the Trump administration and renamed the United States-Mexico-Canada Agreement (USMCA) in 2019. Although USMCA tightened the automotive rules of origin and beefed up the labor-enforcement provisions, it did preserve the core NAFTA benefit of zero tariffs on virtually all goods trade between the three North American neighbors. Since NAFTA, the United States has signed and implemented 12 agreements with 17 countries, using the basic NAFTA framework that subsequent administrations have updated and expanded 

Beyond its economic impact, NAFTA proved to be a valuable foreign-policy initiative. It helped to institutionalize Mexico’s move away from a protected economy under one-party rule, thus improving US relations with its southern neighbor. As trade historian Douglas Irwin concluded, “NAFTA’s biggest impact may have been political: It contributed to the modernization drive that helped diminish the power of the Institutional Revolutionary Party (PRI) that had ruled the country for decades, and move the country towards multi-party democracy.”

In addition to FTAs approved by the United States, it’s also worth noting a major opportunity missed. Under President Barack Obama, US negotiators helped reach an agreement known as the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) that would have expanded those reciprocal zero-tariff benefits to an even wider circle of nations. President Donald Trump, however, withdrew the United States from the TPP shortly after taking office in 2017. The remaining members went ahead and ratified the agreement without the United States. Now dubbed the Comprehensive and Progressive Trans-Pacific Partnership, the agreement includes six current US FTA partners—Canada, Mexico, Peru, Chile, Australia, and Singapore—plus Japan, Malaysia, Vietnam, Brunei, and New Zealand. The United Kingdom also negotiated entry into the agreement and will soon join as its 12th member. South Korea, China, and Taiwan have also applied to join CPTPP. Failure to join the agreement has placed US exporters at a competitive disadvantage and means an added burden for US businesses and consumers importing goods from CPTPP members with whom the United States does not have FTAs.

Why Does the United States Sign FTAs?

Supporters of free trade can raise the objection that trade agreements only complicate the goal of trade liberalization. Why engage in the protracted and sometimes arduous process of negotiating agreements with other countries when the United States could simply pursue free trade on its own by unilaterally liberalizing its own tariffs?

But there are practical as well as historical reasons why trade agreements have played a leading role in American trade policy for much of the past century. As Simon Lester explains, trade agreements make trade liberalization more attractive politically by enlisting US exporters on the side of liberalization. This allows trade liberalization to overcome the opposition of protected industries that would resist any decrease in US tariffs. And trade agreements magnify the benefits of domestic trade liberalization by combining it with trade liberalization abroad. Americans are better off when their government imposes fewer barriers on the freedom to trade—and they are even better off when other governments do the same.

The US International Trade Administration notes that US FTAs address a wide variety of foreign government actions that can affect US businesses, large and small. Besides reducing tariff rates on US exports, FTAs

  • enhance the ability of US exporters to participate in the development of product standards in the FTA partner country;
  • expand the ability of US companies to bid on certain government procurements in the FTA partner country;
  • open opportunities for US service suppliers to sell their services in the FTA partner country; and
  • guarantee that US investors are treated the same as the FTA partner country treats its own investors or those of any third country.

One of the most important advantages of trade agreements is that they lock in trade liberalization gains and prevent backsliding during times of economic stress and political tensions, whether abroad or here at home. In other words, agreements protect us against ourselves and against destructive trade wars that often result when trade barriers are raised unilaterally. During the Great Recession of 2008–2009, a web of trade agreements among advanced economies prevented governments from seeking the politically tempting but economically foolish option of raising trade barriers to “protect” domestic employment. Instead, barriers remained relatively low while governments sought to address the root causes of the downturn.

The Benefits and Downsides of FTAs

Negotiating, approving, and implementing FTAs have both costs and benefits for the United States—and all countries. The impact of these trade agreements on the US economy and employment has been positive, but that impact has also tended to be exaggerated by both sides in the trade debate.

Economic Benefits

Trade agreements’ fundamental purpose is to encourage people to engage in cross-border trade by lowering government barriers thereto, and this liberalization generates significant economic benefits. For example, American families and import-using producers can access a wider variety of imports at lower cost, while American exporters enjoy easier access to markets abroad. Because US trade barriers tend to be lower than most (but far from all!) other nations, the cumulative effect of the trade agreements that the United States has signed has been to lower foreign trade barriers more steeply than US barriers.

As a result, by 2023, 47 percent of US goods exports were bound for countries committed to accepting all exports from the United States duty-free. In return, 38 percent of goods imports to the United States in 2023 came from countries where the US government has committed to accepting their exports duty-free. This marks an important expansion of free trade, and even by the populists’ own logic, this should be the essence of “fair trade.” Almost all US exports to FTA countries are subject to exactly the same tariff rate—0 percent—as the imports we buy from those same countries. What could be more “fair” than that?

Historical experience also helps make the case for FTAs. Presidential candidate H. Ross Perot famously warned in the early 1990s that passage of NAFTA would unleash “a giant sucking sound” of jobs and investment flowing south to lower-wage Mexico. Nothing of the kind happened. In fact, in the five years immediately after the agreement went into effect (1994 through 1998), the US economy grew robustly, the unemployment rate fell to below 4 percent, and a net half a million new manufacturing jobs were created.

Studies by the US International Trade Commission (USITC) and the Peterson Institute for International Economics have found that the overall impact of NAFTA, like other trade agreements, has been modestly positive. While some proponents of the agreement may have overstated its positive impact on jobs, opponents such as Perot and the AFL-CIO were even guiltier of misstating feared negative impacts. According to the USITC, annual outflows of manufacturing foreign direct investment to Mexico during the period examined grew only slightly faster (11.7 percent) than outflows to the rest of the world (9.6 percent). In recent years, annual outflows of manufacturing foreign direct investment to Mexico have averaged less than 2 percent of total annual domestic investment in US manufacturing, and the United States has consistently been the top destination for foreign investment.

Unfortunately, proponents of FTAs have at times oversold their impact with unreasonably precise and optimistic projections of net job creation, export growth, and changes in bilateral trade balances. For example, export growth was disappointing after the signing of FTAs with Mexico and South Korea because of unrelated macroeconomic factors in the partner countries, such as recession. Proponents can also overstate the nontrade impact of agreements on the other country’s domestic political and economic reform. And they can ignore disruptions—lost jobs, for example—that inevitably arise from new foreign competition. It’s a simple fact that politicians are more inclined than professional economists to engage in exaggerated rhetoric to “sell” an agreement. That said, that an agreement may deliver benefits smaller than what proponents promise is not an argument against ratifying the agreement. The net benefits are still positive.

Numerous economic analyses have confirmed these benefits. In a comprehensive 2021 study of the economic impact of trade agreements, for example, the USITC concluded that trade agreements signed by the United States “have had a small, positive effect on the US economy.” The study weighed the economic impact of 16 bilateral and regional agreements with 20 other nations as well as the multilateral 1994 Uruguay Round Agreement that established the WTO.

The USITC analysis determined that the cumulative impact of those agreements has been to boost total US gross domestic product by $88 billion (0.5 percent), average real wages of US workers by 0.3 percent, and total employment by 485,000 full-time equivalent jobs (0.3 percent). Those gains are not spectacular, but they are real, and they refute the dire warnings that enactment of FTAs would lead to slower growth, fewer net jobs, and lower real wages. The opposite is true. The USITC said the gains were driven by economic efficiency gains, higher US employment, and growth in domestic investment, which expands the productive capital stock of the US economy.

The gains were not equally distributed across sectors or income groups, but they were widespread. College-educated workers enjoyed the biggest employment gains, but employment also grew for workers with only a high-school education. The service sector enjoyed most of the economic gains from trade agreements, but the manufacturing sector also grew by $3.5 billion compared to the baseline scenario of no trade agreements. Some manufacturing sectors, such as textiles, did lose jobs because of trade agreements, according to the USITC analysis, but that was caused by efficiency gains within manufacturing and not by an overall decline in output.

Many economists have also noted that the USITC’s methodology tends to understate the economic gains from trade agreements. The USITC analysis focuses on one-time “static gains” as resources shift from less-competitive US sectors to those that are more competitive. Understated are the “dynamic gains” from trade liberalization—such as the new products and production efficiencies stimulated by increased competition and the long-run (if modest) increases in productivity that compound over decades.

Geopolitical Benefits

Aside from more concrete economic benefits, FTAs provide less tangible but still important geopolitical benefits. The enhanced economic interdependence formed by FTAs helps foster stronger diplomatic ties and incentivizes other forms of cooperation among FTA member nations to tackle challenges that transcend political borders. Likewise, FTAs strengthen alliances with like-minded nations and can help counterbalance the geopolitical influence of rival countries such as China. Finally, FTAs are a tool of soft power to influence foreign countries to adopt American-style rules and norms—classic standard setting. For example, Phil Levy analyzed the US-Peru FTA and found that for Peru, the agreement was primarily about locking in the country’s economic liberalization in order to encourage investment, not about tariff reductions.

China’s Entry into the WTO

One of the most misunderstood “trade agreements” in recent US history is technically not a trade agreement at all: the granting of permanent normal trade relations (PNTR) and China’s entry into the WTO. As part of China’s WTO accession, the United States negotiated a bilateral agreement with China in 1999. However, all the obligations to liberalize were on China, and the bilateral agreement did not finalize China’s WTO accession (which entailed bilateral negotiations with several other governments, a multilateral “Working Party Report,” and final consent from all WTO members). In joining the WTO, China agreed to numerous domestic and trade policy reforms, including lowering tariffs on goods imported from all other WTO members—benefits the United States could only access by granting China PNTR. (Without PNTR, China would still enter the WTO but grant additional market access to all members except the United States.)

As a result of the accession and PNTR, Chinese tariffs on US exports were reduced from an average of 25 percent to 7 percent, and the Chinese government relaxed restrictions on US service exports and direct foreign investment while committing to additional protections for US intellectual property. Bilateral trade predictably increased thereafter. From 2001 to 2017 (before COVID-19 and the Trump trade wars), US exports of goods and service to China grew almost eight-fold, from $25 billion to $188 billion; sales by US-owned affiliates in China grew 10-fold, from $33 billion to $345 billion. China is now the top market for US agricultural exports. China’s membership in the WTO has allowed the US government to challenge China’s trade practices in more than 20 cases.

As Scott Lincicome and Arjun Anand detail in a separate essay for this project, PNTR likely did accelerate Chinese imports into the United States, and this heightened import competition likely did result in some US manufacturing job losses. However, economists strongly disagree about the magnitude of this so-called China Shock, which—by even the most severe of estimates—accounted for only about a fifth of the net reduction in manufacturing jobs and only about 5 percent of involuntary job losses between 2000 and 2007. Economists also generally agree that the China Shock produced small but significant economic benefits for American consumers and the US economy as a whole, that Chinese imports remain a small part of Americans’ overall consumption, and that, whatever the China Shock’s impact, it was a one-time, transitory event that will not (and cannot) be repeated.

China’s WTO accession and PNTR also helped to usher China into the system of global trade rules and allowed the US government to pursue several cases through the WTO’s dispute settlement mechanism that resulted in improved Chinese compliance. And opening China’s economy not only increased the sale of US goods and services there (through exports and affiliates) but also helped to lift tens of millions of Chinese people out of abject poverty. China’s WTO membership, especially its post-accession backsliding on protectionism and industrial policy, is certainly not without problems, but few if any of those would be solved by refusing PNTR in 2000 or repealing it today. Instead, China’s economy would have continued to grow, and Chinese goods would have still entered the US market (directly or indirectly), but US companies would have lacked access to China’s market, and the US government would have lacked multilateral mechanisms to negotiate or challenge Chinese economic malfeasance.

Downsides

As noted, even free traders acknowledge that trade agreements are imperfect. For example, the proliferation of FTA trading blocs and customs unions outside of the WTO creates inefficiencies and complications in the multilateral global trading system—setting back the cause of nondiscriminatory multilateral trade. By lowering tariffs on trading bloc members, FTAs can divert trade from a more efficient nonmember exporter to less efficient member exporters—what economists call “trade diversion.” This can concentrate production in a country with higher opportunity costs and lower comparative advantage. Such trade diversion imposes costs not only on the broader global economy but can also harm the importing country because the increased imports may be suboptimal due to price discrimination against a third country’s products.

Beyond tariffs, FTAs create additional rules and regulations, above and beyond what are required under baseline WTO rules.

As trade economist and evangelist for free trade Jagdish Bhagwati wrote in his 2008 book Termites in the Trading System: How Preferential Agreements Undermine Free Trade:

Crisscrossing [preferential trade agreements (PTAs)], where a nation has multiple PTAs with other nations, each of which then had its own PTAs with yet other nations, was inevitable. Indeed, if one only mapped the phenomenon, it would remind one of a child scrawling a number of chaotic lines on a sketch pad … [or a] spaghetti bowl.

This “spaghetti bowl” of rules and rules and regulations make the trading system more complicated to navigate for consumers and businesses.

Trade agreements can also reinforce mercantilist views of trade—exports are a benefit and imports a “concession”—or even lock in protectionism. For example, under the terms of the USMCA, 40 percent of the manufacturing labor incorporated into a passenger vehicle (45 percent for trucks) must have a base wage rate of $16 per hour for an auto to qualify for preferential tariff rates. Given that this rate is substantially above the average auto manufacturing wage in Mexico, it serves as a protectionist tool to ensure a larger share of production of automobiles takes place in the United States, which has higher wages. Other FTA “rules of origin” are similarly protectionist, reducing interparty trade instead of expanding it. In his essay, Lester cites several other examples of such measures, such as intellectual property.

Finally, there is the issue of opportunity cost. Negotiating FTAs is a technical and time-consuming matter, which can divert attention—and negotiators’ and diplomats’ time—away from unilateral liberalization or multilateral negotiations through the WTO system, which is a forum that is more likely to establish nondiscriminatory, near-universally accepted trade rules.

Given these risks, each FTA should not be rubberstamped but instead judged on its merits following a detailed review of its actual provisions (see, e.g., the Cato working paper “Should Free Traders Support the Trans- Pacific Partnership? An Assessment of America’s Largest Preferential Trade Agreement”). In general, however, US FTAs have each liberalized trade on net, and their benefits have substantially outweighed their downsides.

As the United States Dithers, the Rest of the World Is Moving Forward

It has been more than a decade since the United States entered into an FTA with new trading partners and is not currently negotiating any. In fact, the current US trade representative, Katherine Tai, has said that FTAs are “tools of the 20th century,” which is probably news to most of the rest of the world.

As mentioned, CPTPP went into effect without the United States. Today, American consumers pay higher prices for imports from CPTPP nations than they would otherwise; meanwhile, American exporters face higher barriers than competitors within the trading bloc. Though less ambitious than CPTPP, the Beijing-led Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership was implemented in 2022. By sitting on the sidelines, the United States is ceding the ability to shape the rules and norms of international commerce in the Asia Pacific region to others, including China.

The African Continental Free Trade Area, which includes 47 African nations, went into effect in 2018. A more comprehensive deal, the East African Community expanded in 2022 to include the Democratic Republic of Congo and now covers about a quarter of Africa’s population.

The European Union (EU), likewise, has continued to move forward with FTAs with dozens in force, provisionally applied or in negotiation. Following the United Kingdom’s decision to leave the EU, it has entered into a number of FTAs and is negotiating more. The British government is taking the final steps necessary to enter the CPTPP.

India and China—two traditionally protectionist countries—are moving forward with liberalization. India has pursued a robust, liberalizing agreement with Australia and inked an FTA with Norway, Switzerland, Iceland, and Lichtenstein. India is also engaged in FTA talks with the EU. China is negotiating or implementing eight FTAs, on top of the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership and applying to join the CPTPP. In other words, even notoriously protectionist countries are moving forward with liberalization.

As of 2024, the WTO’s database shows there are nearly 370 regional FTAs in force worldwide. The rest of the world continues to move forward with liberalizing FTAs even if the United States does not. Over the long term, a nonexisting trade agenda is a recipe for economic stagnation and a loss of influence around the world. In short, it’s time for Washington to get its act together and get back in the FTA game.

Conclusion

Americans are broadly supportive of US efforts to expand trade with the rest of the world. In its annual polling of public attitudes toward trade, Gallup has found that a solid majority of Americans—more than 60 percent—see foreign trade more as an opportunity compared to 35 percent who view it more as a threat. While trade agreements are hotly debated in Congress, they are seldom a central issue in elections. Despite ever-present political pressure from protectionist interest, US politicians enjoy ample political space to do the right thing by negotiating and enacting further trade agreements.

The rest of the world is even keener on FTAs. The WTO has counted more than 300 FTAs in effect; this includes 100 negotiated in the past decade, while over the same period, the United States has signed none. US dawdling on the sidelines means that US exporters increasingly face discriminatory tariffs in those countries while their competitors in FTA countries enjoy duty-free access to those markets. US businesses that rely on imported inputs are similarly placed on the backfoot in a competitive global market. The United States and its most competitive producers are being left behind as the world moves ahead in lowering trade barriers.

Trade agreements have played an important and positive role in expanding the freedom of Americans to engage in commerce with the rest of the world. Those agreements have opened markets for hundreds of billions of dollars of US exports and foreign investment while lifting the standard of living for millions of American families through lower consumer prices and better jobs. Those agreements have brought the rule of law and equal treatment to global commerce while discouraging politicians from retreating into destructive trade wars during times of economic challenge.

To read the essay as it was published on the Cato Institute webpage, click here.

The post How Trade Agreements Have Enhanced the Freedom and Prosperity of Americans appeared first on WITA.

]]>
U.S. Engagement in the Indo-Pacific: Don’t Trade Away Trade /atp-research/dont-trade-away/ Tue, 25 Jun 2024 20:49:50 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=47682 A different approach to trade in Asia could represent a middle way between the Biden administration’s current approach and the so-called Washington Consensus of old.   International trade has been...

The post U.S. Engagement in the Indo-Pacific: Don’t Trade Away Trade appeared first on WITA.

]]>
A different approach to trade in Asia could represent a middle way between the Biden administration’s current approach and the so-called Washington Consensus of old.

 

International trade has been a pillar of U.S. foreign and domestic policy for most of the post–World War II era. Policymakers from both major parties have treated strong international economic relationships built on expanding international trade as central to advancing economic growth at home and achieving American goals on international development and security abroad. Secretary of the Treasury Janet Yellen captured the old consensus position well in an April 2023 speech explaining that “our economic power is amplified because we don’t stand alone. America values our close friends and partners in every region of the world, including the Indo-Pacific. In the 21st century, no country in isolation can create a strong and sustainable economy for its people.” Her words echoed those of one of her predecessors, Henry Paulson, who remarked sixteen years earlier on the benefits of open economic exchange that “countries that weren’t afraid of competition, that opened themselves up to trade, competition and trade, investment and finance, benefited, [whereas] the rest of the world, others were left behind. And opening . . . up to this competition leads to innovation, it leads to better jobs, more jobs, it leads to a higher standard of living.”

But in a very different April 2023 speech, U.S. President Joe Biden’s national security adviser, Jake Sullivan, laid out the administration’s case against globalization as it had been pursued in the past and argued for a new economic approach. While acknowledging that international economic cooperation “lifted hundreds of millions of people out of poverty” and “sustained thrilling technological revolutions,” he also argued that it all came at a price. To wit: “A shifting global economy left many working Americans and their communities behind.” The inexorable push for scrapping trade barriers had other costs, too, he continued—among them, the hollowing out of America’s industrial base, inequality that has threatened U.S. democracy, increasing environmental consequences, and geopolitical risks created by dependence on rivals such as China.

According to Sullivan, the Biden administration was forging a new path: not one that entirely rejected trade liberalization, but also not one that embraced traditional free trade agreements or tariff reductions as the main destination. He framed the approach as a middle ground, focused on advancing economic cooperation by pursuing nontrade priorities such as supply chain resilience, secure digital infrastructure, sustainable clean energy transition, and job creation. Sullivan described a new economic model that would be worker-centric, combining industrial policy to support high priority sectors with efforts to harmonize labor and environmental standards and integrate supply chains with close allies and partners—but without offering new market access.

Admittedly, Biden has achieved a measure of success in working toward this vision. Domestically, there were important wins included in the Bipartisan Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act, the CHIPS and Science Act, and the Inflation Reduction Act. Appropriated funding is being doled out to boost semiconductor production and spark investment in other cutting-edge technologies. Money in these bills will also support infrastructure development that creates manufacturing jobs and helps to rebuild parts of the industrial base, including those that support national defense.

On the other hand, success abroad has been more limited, even if not absent. The Biden administration has improved coordination with European allies in areas such as green technologies and artificial intelligence, supply chain integration, and critical minerals, for example. In Asia, Biden’s team has advanced the Indo-Pacific Economic Framework (IPEF) with thirteen other participants and reached agreements on issues such as supply chains, clean energy and infrastructure, and tax and anti-corruption efforts.

But there is a larger story. Whatever the intention of these narrow efforts, Biden’s economic approach has resulted in a doubling down on the harder turn away from relatively free trade that began under former president Donald Trump’s administration—a set of outcomes different from what Sullivan’s speech appeared to imply. The promised middle ground has remained elusive. Although Biden’s team has not officially “sworn off” market liberalization, expanded market access appears to have been almost completely shelved as a foreign policy tool—even when it would have significant benefits or could serve as an incentive to push progress toward key security and geopolitical objectives.

Nowhere has this been clearer or more consequential than in Asia—home to many of the fastest-growing economies in the world. Though the administration has signed trade “mini-deals” based on executive orders with Japan and Vietnam in limited sectors and encouraged continued U.S. leadership in private investment, it has relied on the IPEF as the main vector of U.S. economic policy in the region. The IPEF has explicitly excluded market access from negotiations across all four pillars, a decision that has limited its scope and durability. For example, without trade as an incentive, IPEF members have been hesitant to commit to costly reforms related to issues like climate change or worker protection, resulting in a set of agreements that are mostly aspirational and without credible enforcement mechanisms. The evolution of the IPEF’s trade pillar is also telling. Not only did the trade pillar’s draft framework agreement exclude tariff reductions but the United States pulled out of negotiations on this agreement in November 2023, leaving the pillar stalled indefinitely.

Washington’s reliance on the IPEF as its main economic lever in Asia has magnified other risks as well, including lost opportunities to consolidate geopolitical influence and strengthen relationships with allies and partners. Though the United States remains a major economic force in the region, private investment and executive trade agreements cannot replace a more expansive approach to trade in Asia when it comes to integrating the United States more deeply into the region’s multilateral economic networks.

Without a more robust trade agenda, Washington misses out on economic opportunities. For example, the United States has limited leverage to shape the rules for economic exchange in Asia while they are being rewritten to incorporate new global realities like the economic power of India, Japan, and South Korea, the spread of fast-evolving technologies and digital trade, and the pressures of climate change and global migration. Even U.S. security goals in Asia are compromised by American policymakers’ decision to eschew trade policy as a foreign policy tool. U.S. allies and partners, who are heavily dependent on trade with China and lacking many economic alternatives, are limited in how closely they can align with Washington in the security domain for fear of economic retaliation from Beijing.

A different approach to trade in Asia—and globally—can exist in the space between past policies and those of the present, one that would truly represent a middle way between the current approach and the so-called Washington Consensus of old. Such a strategy would amount to a more reflective version of global integration that attends carefully to domestic realities alongside interests abroad while retaining trade as a key foreign policy tool that links the economic and security domains.

The new approach would allow for some heterodoxy in economic policy across regions and sectors and would aim to revitalize the Biden administration’s current industrial policy with a series of trade innovations, such as mini-lateral and sectoral trade agreements with key partners, efforts to integrate key Asian allies more deeply into existing multilateral agreements, or modifications to attach some limited market access to the IPEF. Each expansion of market access would be narrow and tied to clearly defined criteria, but together these moves would be enough to reestablish trade as a foreign policy lever in a crucial region. These trade innovations would not replace government protection for strategic industries, and a substantial and immediate increase in federal spending on government training and assistance for dislocated workers would still be required.

With this type of approach, the United States could better communicate its economic and geopolitical commitment to the region, diversify its economic role in Asia, and position itself to compete more effectively with China, even as it protects key U.S. industries. The United States would still need to manage some risks, of course, including finding the balance between engagement and competition with China, relative and absolute economic gains, and national prosperity and security. Even with these challenges, the pursuit of this true middle ground should be a top priority in Washington.

Economic Integration and Its Discontents

In the early twenty-first century, questions for U.S. policymakers about how best to approach the intertwined issues of cross-border trade, migration, flows of information, and political ties in Asia occur alongside a broader backlash against “globalization.” At a time of major geopolitical upheaval and technological change, policymakers and the public are vigorously debating the merits of domestic policies suitable for an interconnected world. They are exploring new trade and migration rules, reviving strategies for national industrial and technological development, and reflecting on the lessons of globalization for international law and institutions substantially influenced by the United States. Discussions of “reshoring” supply chains and U.S.-China economic “decoupling” or “de-risking” are just a few examples of rising concerns in Washington about cross-border ties.

Despite occasional protestations from policymakers about the need for balance, the debate thus far has been mostly concentrated on the extremes: globalization that pushes for ever more economic cooperation or industrial policy that focuses inward to protect domestic jobs. Often lost in this debate, however, is that both of these approaches have substantial benefits and significant costs. This is true both globally and narrowly in Asia.

The U.S. commitment to comprehensive free trade has always been qualified. Even the World Trade Organization (WTO) embodies a contingent—not absolute—form of free trade. In this conditional form, globalization has had clear advantages for the United States. Most significantly, it has been responsible for tremendous domestic economic growth. The U.S. per capita GDP (in constant 2010 dollars) was about $19,000 in 1960 and $61,000 in 2021 (four times the global average per capita GDP, considerably higher than any other country with a large population)—a feat that would not have been possible without trade and international economic cooperation. Trade with Asia specifically has and continues to provide the United States with significant economic gains. As of 2019, for instance, exports to Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) member states alone accounted for over 500,000 jobs in the United States.

Though domestic economic growth has been the primary driver of Washington’s long-running support for free trade, the United States has also profited in other ways from its perch atop a cooperative international economic order. Adam Posen, president of the Peterson Institute for International Economics, argues that “as creator and enforcer of international economic rules,” the United States gained “maximum economic traction while minimizing the need for direct conflict” and “could even occasionally flout the rules, or tweak them in its favor.” International economic integration also allowed for specialization, faster innovation, higher returns on capital investments, economies of scale, and other efficiencies that benefited the American economy and U.S. workers.

The United States has also accrued international influence through economic cooperation. Much U.S. soft power, globally and in Asia, depends on the fact that billions around the world consume the ideas and technologies produced in major metro areas around the United States—metro areas that have evolved into the key pillars of U.S. global leadership in science and medicine, media and culture, education, civic life, and digital technology. Often, they encompass diasporas from South Asia, East Asia, and elsewhere, and depend on constant influxes of new visitors and residents—including students and workers from other states and countries—who bring new ideas and investment. International economic cooperation contributes to this mobility of capital, people, and ideas.

Globalization as it was pursued and implemented over the past several decades, however, has also had costs––some real and some imagined or overstated. Most importantly, the benefits from global trade are rarely evenly distributed and contributed to a sharp drop in U.S. manufacturing jobs over several decades as corporations shifted production to countries with cheaper labor. One National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) estimate, for instance, finds that between 1980 and 2017—a peak period in globalization—the United States lost 7.5 million manufacturing jobs, with trade being one of several drivers. Not only did this loss of manufacturing erode the U.S. industrial base, it also disproportionately affected workers with only a high school diploma. Many were left dislocated when government-promoted retraining and assistance programs were underfunded and insufficient.

These economic costs may have had political ramifications as well. Some analyses suggest that Trump’s 2016 victory was made possible by voters on the losing end of the inexorable press for trade liberalization, who had voted for former president Barack Obama in 2012 but were won over by Trump’s promise to bring back U.S. manufacturing jobs by reducing trade with China and pulling the United States out of the ambitious Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP)—which he ultimately did.

That said, questions persist about just how much trade liberalization alone contributed to what Sullivan called the “hollowing out” of U.S. manufacturing or to Trump’s 2016 victory. A 2021 analysis by the Center for Strategic and International Studies, for instance, shows that increasing worker productivity, not trade, accounts for the greatest share of the decline in U.S. manufacturing jobs. This is supported by research from the Ohio State University that found trade was only responsible for a third of manufacturing job losses in that state. Of this total lost to trade, only a relatively smaller percentage can be linked directly to trade with China specifically—estimates of this percentage vary but most fall between 10 and 25 percent. Moreover, there is evidence that negative effects of the “China shock” occurred largely before 2010 and did not persist afterward, suggesting that fear of continued manufacturing job losses to China and elsewhere may be misplaced.

The argument that economic costs from trade drove the societal implications many observers ascribe to cross-border commerce also lacks clear support. Even if trade effects are understood to play some role in rising political tensions within the United States, a close examination of voting trends from the 2016 election recognize cultural factors—rather than purely economic hardship—to be the key factors behind changes in partisan politics.

The economic and political costs of globalization may be somewhat more measured than expected, but unchecked economic integration can raise material national security questions. Many in Congress and the executive agencies caution that too much trade creates dependencies that would turn into vulnerabilities in a conflict. These fears are especially acute, and at least partially justified, when it comes to trade in Asia and with China specifically, given the critical imports that this trade includes, the rising risk of conflict in the region, and what many view as unfair trade practices employed by Beijing. The United States remains heavily dependent on China for some critical minerals, for example, including those necessary for advanced military systems. China’s military-civilian fusion also creates the potential for U.S. exports to China to end up supporting the development of its People’s Liberation Army. And China has shown a willingness to use economic retaliation as a tool of coercion and to manipulate its currency and markets in ways that disadvantage U.S. firms.

These challenges are all reasons that the United States may need to manage trade with China carefully, including restricting certain types of exports and protecting some domestic industries. They are not, however, a reason to entirely give up further trade integration with the rest of Asia or elsewhere. In fact, geopolitical competition makes the development of a strong trade agenda globally, and in Asia especially, more important for the United States, not less. This is true for two reasons.

First, by turning away from market access as a foreign policy tool in Asia, Washington cedes much of the trade domain to Beijing, leaving its partners with fewer economic alternative and undermining U.S. influence in Asia. Second, some additional trade integration with countries across Asia (and outside of it) could help the United States build a more diversified and resilient supply chain and trade network itself, reducing its dependence on China in key sectors. Achieving this outcome would require intentional choices about how and where to increase trade access, but it cannot be achieved when trade liberalization is not an option. Biden’s economic strategy in Asia, and the IPEF in its current form especially, is not up to the job, either at the institutional level or its basic orientation to the role of trade in U.S. foreign policy.

The Risks of Biden’s Approach to Trade in Asia

The Biden administration’s reluctance to use market access as a foreign policy tool has global ripple effects but the risks are biggest in Asia, both because of the region’s high and growing economic importance across sectors and because it is home to the most important U.S. strategic and economic competitor: China. As a result, when thinking about the future of U.S. trade policy, it makes sense to start in the Indo-Pacific.

The administration’s economic strategy in the region has included a few key pieces: “mini-deals” signed at the executive level to increase bilateral trade in specific sectors with close allies and partners; initiatives to advance regional supply chain cooperation, especially in the defense sector and for technologies like semiconductors; economic incentives to spur private business investment in the region; export controls and industrial policy to protect domestic industry and national security; and, at the center, the IPEF, which is intended to unite these different initiatives.

As conceived by the Biden administration, the IPEF was loosely intended to offset the U.S. decision not to join the TPP and its successor organization, the Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership (CPTPP). The IPEF focuses on reducing nontariff barriers to trade, especially harmonizing standards. The IPEF’s largest successes thus far have been in establishing an agreement to support supply chain integration and resilience among the thirteen other participating members and acceptance of a set of standards to advance climate goals and fight corruption.

However, the IPEF’s first set of agreements leave much to be desired. For the most part, they include only nonbinding commitments and high-level ambitions, rather than clear and actionable targets for cooperation. The IPEF’s pillars also remain weakly institutionalized, making it unclear how standards will be monitored or enforced. At this point, it remains uncertain whether the three agreements signed thus far—in the climate, tax and anti-corruption, and supply chain pillars—will advance U.S. economic integration in the region. Moreover, the trade pillar lacks a path forward after the United States pulled out of negotiations, much to the dismay of other participants. The IPEF has also failed to win the confidence of constituents across Asia. A 2024 survey of Southeast Asian states found that respondents appear to be growing more skeptical and critical of the IPEF over time, resent the high cost of achieving U.S.-promoted standards with few benefits in return, and identify China as the economic leader in the region while questioning U.S. staying power and commitment.

Beyond these institutional shortcomings, the IPEF-led approach to trade in Asia and the failure to find a real middle way in the trade domain come with three types of risk, each with potential economic and geopolitical costs. Notably, even if more pronounced in Asia, these challenges are not entirely unique to the region and exist elsewhere as well.

First, by remaining outside of all of Asia’s major trade agreements, the United States is likely to face losses in terms of GDP and domestic economic growth. In this case, much (but not all) of the U.S. economic loss is likely to translate into gains for China. As the United States has moved away from free trade, China has leaned into it. With its involvement in the ASEAN+3, ASEAN+6, bilateral trade agreements, and now the new Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership (RCEP), China’s trade with Southeast Asia has quadrupled since 2009 (compared to a smaller but still sizeable tripling of its global trade). A study by the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development found further that the RCEP arrangement would reduce U.S. exports to Asia by over $5 billion due to trade diverting away from the United States and toward RCEP partners where tariffs are lower.

Membership in the CPTPP would have placed the United States on more equal footing and offered benefits that far exceed any RCEP-induced losses. By choosing not to join this organization, the United States misses out on billions in economic gains. A 2018 Peterson Institute report found that joining the CPTPP would have resulted in net $131 billion added to U.S. GDP by 2030, while the decision to pull out will result in a $2 billion loss. By expanding market access to Asian partners—at least in some sectors and to some partners—the United States could lay claim to some portion of this windfall. The narrow bilateral executive agreements signed under Biden move in the right direction but are too limited to offset the deficit created by the weakness of other aspects of Biden’s trade and economic strategy.

None of these observations imply that the United States should mirror China’s approach to trade in Asia or elsewhere. After all, the two countries face quite different dynamics when it comes to international trade’s inherent trade-offs. China sees in free trade agreements a way to gain access to new export markets and a solution to its large trade surpluses. The United States, in contrast, often finds itself as what economist and Carnegie Scholar Michael Pettis calls the “absorber of last resort” for its own trade partners, hence its reluctance to sign on to large multilateral trade deals. It is for this reason that a return to the more aggressive embrace of free trade seen in previous decades is not the right approach for the United States today. The Biden administration’s current strategy may go too far in the other direction, however, where a more balanced approach might capture some economic gains while still protecting relevant domestic interests.

Second, Washington’s position outside Asia’s major economic organizations undermines its efforts to increase and consolidate influence with regional allies and partners. At one level, the mechanism for this loss of influence is straightforward. Limits on market access that slow the diffusion of U.S. goods and raise prices on U.S. technology and other products limit U.S. soft power gains and constrain its geopolitical leverage at the same time.

These missed opportunities to garner greater geopolitical sway with regional allies also arise at a deeper level. For countries across Asia, the unwillingness of the United States to join the CPTPP or to offer meaningful expansion of market access through bilateral agreements signals a lack of serious commitment to the region. Many of these states are already skeptical of the durability of the U.S. focus on Asia, seeing it is as a distracted and unreliable partner. The constraints the United States has placed on the IPEF only exacerbate this perception and lead many countries in the region to look elsewhere for economic opportunities. For instance, because its framework agreements are signed at the executive level only, the IPEF lacks the longevity that would promote long-term U.S. investment. The U.S. decision to withdraw from the trade pillar negotiations did further damage to regional perceptions of U.S. credibility.

What’s more, for countries in the region, the more limited U.S. integration into the region’s trade networks and economic groupings is not just an economic concern (though many have chafed under the new U.S. protectionism and unilateralism). Because it leaves them more beholden to an increasingly aggressive Beijing, less U.S. trade engagement in Asia becomes an important security challenge as well—a manifestation of the often-cited link between economic well-being and national security. Countries in Asia seek to diversify their economic partnerships to reduce their dependence on China and would readily welcome more involvement from the United States to increase their resilience and economic options. Under Biden, however, even those who are members of the IPEF have been left disappointed as the United States has refused to extend any sort of market access. Countries across Asia have been left with little choice but to remain dependent on China as its primary trade partner.

These economic pressures can have real security consequences. Countries like Indonesia and Malaysia, for example, tread carefully in territorial disputes with China for fear of upsetting their trade relationships. Even countries for whom the threat from China appears more existential, such as Japan and Vietnam, are pragmatic in their dealings with Beijing to preserve economic ties. Recognizing the liability this economic dependence creates, even allies and partners that support U.S. efforts in Asia’s security domain in principle may be forced to stay on the sidelines of a U.S.-China conflict to protect their economic well-being. This could have serious implications for U.S. efforts to rally a coalition to contain Chinese aggression.

Finally, by forgoing a more robust approach to trade in the region, the United States gives up an opportunity to participate in the writing and updating of Asia’s rules on economic exchange to include things like labor and digital trade standards or climate mitigation. These issues have an outsized effect on the Indo-Pacific region, and sensible responses to all are affected by trade integration and related questions about cross-border flows of investment, technology, and people. For example, years after an American objection to WTO Appellate Body appointments threw a wrench in the gears of the global trade organization, the WTO dispute resolution process remains paralyzed. In the face of this obstacle, other WTO members have developed work-arounds. The EU and key Pacific countries and emerging powers have strung together one interim alternative that Japan just joined, and Europe is pursuing a broader trade settlement with Asian countries extending to subsidies and related issues. By standing aside, American policymakers forfeit their influence over the resulting mechanisms and reinforce the message that the United States is not the one driving Asia’s economic or diplomatic future.

Asia’s climate crisis offers another illustrative example. Its average temperature is rising at about three times the global rate, exacerbated by rapid industrialization. Elevated sea levels threaten coastal areas, putting pressure on farmland and major cities. The mining of critical minerals found in abundance in parts of Southeast Asia—in high demand by the United States and countries around the world—is of particular concern because the processes used to extract these minerals can severely damage surrounding ecosystems. While the increasing trade volumes that result from trade liberalization are not the sole or even the most prominent driver of climate disruption, the increase in economic activity and manufacturing that accompany rising trade do absorb more natural resources and contribute to air and water pollution, making an already bad situation worse. Collective solutions will be needed to balance economic demand and these environmental challenges, but the United States can only shape resulting outcomes if it is a participant in the region’s trade and economic networks.

For policymakers in places like Singapore, Hanoi, Manila, and Jakarta, the long list of looming challenges—including but not limited to climate change—also serves as a reminder that all politics are primarily local and regional. The competition between the United States and China—however important to understand and manage—ought not eclipse the broader range of security and economic questions facing the region as a whole. Addressing these challenges will require some degree of international cooperation and a new set of rules of the road for regional economic exchange that take collective costs into account. Governing the remarkably fast-evolving technologies and the rapid growth of the digital economy will also prove to be part of that story.

To have a say in this process and a seat at this table, the United States must be more active in the region’s expansive web of trade networks. In 2022, these networks accounted for about 40 percent of global exports and imports and trillions of dollars in global commerce. The United States is a country of unique global power and sway. Its unusual history of outsized influence has left an indelible mark on the frameworks for global cooperation and integration, and it was the principal architect of the post–World War II economic order. As that order confronts the reality of forced adaptation, it is not a stretch to think that Washington can and should play a role as those frameworks are updated for the realities of Asia today and contemporary global economic and political challenges. Other countries in the region are not sitting idly by waiting for the United States to engage more seriously on these issues, however. China, South Korea, Japan, India, and others are already building their own rules and standards, sometimes together but often independently.

Achieving an Authentic Middle Way

Even if the United States and China find reliable ways to cooperate on elements of that emerging order—on matters ranging from climate change to AI safety—the two countries have differing values and strategic priorities. The resulting geopolitical competition with China makes the development of a more robust U.S. trade agenda in Asia desirable despite the risks. New military partnerships, investments in allied capabilities, deployments of advanced technologies, and multilateral exercises are necessary but not sufficient for the United States to remain a counterweight able to balance Chinese power in the region. A change in the administration’s trade policy will be required as well. Countries in Asia would benefit from a more active U.S. trade presence but a shift in trade strategy would not be charity project—it would be directly aligned with U.S. interests and could inform efforts to make better use of trade as foreign policy tool in other regions as well.

Whatever course is chosen in Asia and elsewhere will need to balance domestic adjustments (across job types and economic sectors) with the gains from a greater degree of economic cooperation. Addressing these costs will require holistic strategies and more nuanced approaches that, for example, reflect distinctions in the educational opportunities suitable for people at different points in their life, reliably reduce a measure of economic risk, and open new employment and civic opportunities. Policymakers likely already understand these requirements but are also searching for ways to make some degree of trade liberalization more politically palatable and to ensure that promised educational and economic support does not fall through as it has in the past. By better understanding the long-simmering conflicts over global cooperation, policymakers and civil society can further develop the ideas, institutions, and coalitions necessary to create a stable foundation for a more sustainable form of global integration.

Nothing about this challenge means that U.S. policymakers should walk away from once again using market access as a tool to keep American interests relevant in one of the world’s most important regions. The task at hand is to create pathways for the exchange of information, ideas, and culture, while policymakers retain at least a limited set of tools to address imbalances that arise if considerable movements of goods and capital coexist with completely inflexible migration policies. Indeed, policymakers with influence over the international system should always bear in mind the costs of coercive limitations on the movement of ideas, goods, information, and people across borders, even if such constraints are also necessary for national-level experimentation and the functioning of countries as currently configured.

In that vein, the preservation of rules that enable international trade—even as policymakers tolerate somewhat more heterodox economic policies—would benefit the United States and its allies, resulting in trade rules of narrower application to countries’ domestic policies but reliably enforced and written with an eye toward more equitable global development. This would mean, in part, pursuing many pathways to expanded economic cooperation, including some reform of the WTO and the rules governing global, multilateral trade, alongside domestically focused initiatives to compensate and offer viable retraining opportunities to those that are displaced. To this end, U.S. leaders should focus on several promising levers as first steps.

First, policymakers should take a lesson from U.S. advances in Asia’s security domain and turn to mini-laterals—groups of three to five countries focused on a narrow set of issues with shared interests as a way to achieve the gains of cooperation with less risk. Without entirely casting aside the prospect for more ambitious deals, this approach would avoid making the perfect the enemy of the good. The intent would be to work with a limited group of partners in targeted sectors—building off the administration’s mini-deal approach, but with significantly wider participation, more heft, and the consistent message that the goal is to recapture momentum on market access rather than cast aside entirely the prospects for more comprehensive deals.

Regional mechanisms like mini-laterals are far from perfect, but they offer a degree of interconnectedness that can enhance deliberation across borders and make policy responses more appropriately nuanced. Working with just a small group of like-minded partners, the United States would have greater leverage to set and enforce high labor, climate, and other standards. Picking and choosing sectors to focus on would allow the United States to avoid areas of political sensitivity and seize on opportunities to advance other strategic objectives.

Supply chain diplomacy, for instance, can indeed result in progress, as evident in the agreements the United States has recently signed on coproduction and technology with India, Australia, and Japan.

Expanding these areas of growing cooperation into the trade domain and adding new tailored agreements with countries across Southeast Asia should be high on the list of priorities for those guiding U.S. trade policy. Although there is some value in pursuing such deals, as Peter Harrell has argued in Foreign Affairs, “in sectors where interests clearly converge,” it will be important to remember that other countries get a vote, too. They will often prefer more comprehensive agreements that will require U.S. policymakers to take on a measure of responsibility for garnering political support and designing suitable mechanisms to mitigate the impact on affected communities.

Indeed, relying on a mini-lateral approach comes with risks. While reaching agreements with a smaller number of partners can be comparatively easier than achieving the consensus needed for a large multilateral agreement, transaction costs are still involved. Too many of these small, overlapping groups can create a crowded international economic architecture, which can be costly and difficult to manage. Washington will therefore need to be judicious in selecting the partners and sectors where it invests in building new institutions for cooperative economic exchange. The tendency will be to lean toward partners like Japan and South Korea where higher levels of economic development may make agreements with high standards easier to reach. But this may have downsides, too, in that it will constrain pathways to economic integration across other parts of Asia—especially Southeast Asia, where much of the region’s growth potential is located. To guard against this, the United States should aim to diversify its partners and explicitly focus on building mini-lateral agreements with countries who are not already U.S. treaty allies.

The United States will also need to pursue trade reengagement through other channels to achieve the desired diversity in economic cooperation. One option might be to find ways to add some limited market access to a more institutionalized IPEF, tied to strict technology standards, for example, with clear mechanisms for enforcement and monitoring. Bringing close Asian partners like Japan into existing free trade agreements like the United States-Mexico-Canada Agreement (USMCA) if they are willing to adhere to its higher standards and requirements is another option. Ways to expand and leverage existing bilateral agreements, especially with nontraditional partners who are strategically important or show high potential for economic cooperation, should also be explored. The bottom line is that policymakers will need to be creative to find varied opportunities with the right balance of economic gains and domestic safeguards.

Alongside the pursuit of a modest and controlled market liberalization abroad, Washington must also carefully attend to associated domestic costs. It can do this in two ways. The first is to continue to rely on industrial policy to protect sectors of high strategic importance to the United States. As under the Biden administration thus far, this would likely include semiconductors, green technologies, and several others. That said, policymakers should develop far clearer metrics or criteria to determine which sectors require protection and subsidies to support U.S. interests. This list would likely be somewhat shorter than the set of industries that receive this type of support today. Second, policymakers will need to redouble their efforts to compensate and retrain workers who suffer due to trade’s distributional effects. This is an area where governments have fallen short in the past, and more robust commitment and better outcomes will be essential to the success of any reengagement with trade. Significant federal funding and coordination will be required and should be allocated. Moreover, programs would need to be aimed at more diverse audiences with more flexible types of assistance.

For U.S. policymakers, engaging with a more ambitious trade agenda can contribute to greater security and shared growth across Asia and in the United States. Policymakers can advance that agenda without ignoring the potential for trade-related economic displacement to affect communities in the United States—a challenge that persists even if many of our most dynamic regions grow stronger because of economic relationships with Asia. With the right carve-outs and attention to supply chain resilience as well as the situation of Asian trading partners, a more vigorous trade agenda can also fit with American national security goals and reasonable domestic needs. Congress and the executive have multiple tools to meet the moment without neglecting the role of market access in strategy and standard-setting: from savvy use of existing bilateral trade relationships to new mini-lateral groups that can expand trade across sectors, market-oriented reforms to the IPEF, and efforts to piggyback off existing free trade agreements such as the USMCA. Greater attention to workers and communities adjusting to new economic realities is also likely a sensible response. So, too, is the targeted use of industrial policy alongside carefully calibrated efforts to reform multilateral trade rules to make international trade more compatible with domestic needs. Closing off any serious near-term prospect for greater access to the American market is not.

Jennifer Kavanagh was a senior fellow in the American Statecraft Program at the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. Mariano-Florentino (Tino) Cuéllar is the tenth president of the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace

Kavanagh_Cuellar_Trade in Asia

To read the full paper published by the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, click here.

To read the full paper, click here.

The post U.S. Engagement in the Indo-Pacific: Don’t Trade Away Trade appeared first on WITA.

]]>
The Conservative Case & The Progressive Case for Globalization /atp-research/cons-prog/ Thu, 30 May 2024 19:15:31 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=46043 As part of the Cato Institute’s 5-part series, Defending Globalization: Law and Politics, the following two essays were published on May 30th, 2024. “The Conservative Case for Globalization,” authored by...

The post The Conservative Case & The Progressive Case for Globalization appeared first on WITA.

]]>
As part of the Cato Institute’s 5-part series, Defending Globalization: Law and Politics, the following two essays were published on May 30th, 2024. “The Conservative Case for Globalization,” authored by Jeb Hensarling, can be found below. Following it is “The Progressive Case for Globalization” by Inu Manak and Helena Kopans-Johnson.

 

The Conservative Case for Globalization

Many self‐​styled conservative talking heads and members of Congress are calling for industrial policy, forms of wage and price controls, and new federal agencies to police free speech. Such positions have historically been anathema to the conservative movement and should remain so. Along with these issues, there is likely no other issue more timely or relevant to the question of just who is—and what is—a conservative than the issue of globalized free trade.

History

To settle the question of who may legitimately claim the title of “conservative” today, a quick reminder of the movement’s origins and evolution and their relation to trade is helpful. Although admittedly there is no universally held definition of conservatism, there have been broadly recognized and accepted core principles, as well a proud historical lineage. The English parliamentarian and philosopher Edmund Burke is generally recognized as the father of conservatism. Burke, throughout his career, advocated for freer trade. He understood that trade is not a zero‐​sum game between countries. In supporting reduced trade barriers between Britain and Ireland, Burke argued, “The prosperity which arises from an enlarged and liberal system improves all of its objects; and the participation of trade with flourishing Countries is much better than a monopoly of want and penury.”

His arguments included those based on economic utilitarian grounds. For example, he argued in Parliament that a free market without government interference is the best method to help the poor. As conservatives today continue to fight the rise of the social welfare state, they have historically recognized, as did Burke, that cost‐​increasing protectionism simply creates greater welfare dependency, not less.

Burke’s more impassioned and important argument, however, rested upon a recognition and reliance upon natural rights (conservatives should think, “We hold these truths to be self‐​evident …”). Burke believed that these rights clearly entitled and protected an individual’s right to both own property and to trade it freely.

For decades, most conservatives have proudly viewed themselves as free‐​market conservatives, a moniker whose principled intellectual foundation rests upon Adam Smith’s classic work An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Noteworthy, Smith was a friend and contemporary of Burke. Smith skewered the prevailing mercantilist and protectionist policies of the day and argued on utilitarian grounds that freedom of trade across international borders benefited the masses. He wrote, “Trade which, without force or constraint, is naturally and regularly carried on between any two places is always advantageous.” Some modern‐​day conservatives have now begun relying on the limited exceptions to the free trade rule (e.g., national defense) that Smith enumerated in his work to justify their protectionism. But any plausible reading of Smith indicates that these exceptions are just that—exceptions—which he further explained were rarely justified and often subject to abuse.

Today one of the greatest accolades within the conservative movement is that of “constitutional conservative,” a term meant to convey fealty to the Founding principles contained within the Declaration of Independence and US Constitution. Any conservative would be well advised to carefully reread the Declaration’s list of the repeated “injuries and usurpations” of the Crown, which evidenced its tyranny and justified American independence. The list includes “cutting off our Trade with all parts of the World.” Thomas Paine, author of Common Sense, the most influential pamphlet of the Revolutionary Era, wrote that to a trading country, freedom of trade was “of such importance, that the principal source of wealth depends on it; and it is impossible that any country can flourish … whose commerce is … fettered by laws of another.… A freedom from the restraints of the Acts of Navigation I foresee will produce … immense additions to the wealth of this country.”

In addition to Paine, most Founders believed in the goal of free trade and viewed it as necessary for the prosperity of the republic. They believed the principal and proper use of tariffs should be limited to revenue raising, not protecting domestic industries. In fact, at the dawn of our republic and for more than a century thereafter, the bulk of tax revenues were derived from import duties, given their relative ease of collection, as Phil Magness lays out in his Cato Institute essay on the history of tariffs in the United States between 1787 and 1934. The other recognized legitimate use of tariffs was to incentivize other nations to open their borders to our trade. These purposes are in distinct contrast to the purposes proposed by many today who seek to engage in industrial policy that benefits discreet economic sectors or industries or that promotes economic nationalism designed to severely limit or close off our international trade.

Article l, Section 8 of the Constitution unequivocally gives Congress the power to both “regulate Commerce with foreign Nations” and to “lay and collect Taxes, Duties.” Because of this section, some argue that conservatives stand on firm constitutional ground in favoring the imposition of tariffs. It should be noted that Section 8 also empowers Congress to borrow money. Given the magnitude and dangerous trajectory of the national debt, few conservatives believe the exercise of such power a wise one. The same is true for the imposition of tariffs.

Finally, the most conservative leader of the 20th century, President Ronald Reagan, confidently proclaimed that in America, “Our trade policy rests firmly on the foundation of free and open markets.” Although Reagan did implement some protectionist measures, they were part of his broader efforts to stave off even worse protectionism from Congress and to push for broader liberalization through the US‐​Canada Free Trade Agreement (the North American Free Trade Agreement’s [NAFTA’s] predecessor) and the US‐​Israel Free Trade Agreement, as well as launching negotiations that led to the creation of the World Trade Organization (WTO), the successor to the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). Trade doubled on his watch.

There has been debate over the use of tariffs ever since America became a constitutional republic. There have been times in our history when, regrettably, tariffs carried the day. And certainly, there have been tariffs enacted that have arguably fallen into Smith’s enumerated and limited exceptions. What isn’t debatable is that the conservative movement has always rested on a firm foundation of personal freedom, including economic freedom, based on natural rights, and at least in the post–World War II era, this has always included the freedom to trade.

Thirty‐​five years after Reagan, President Donald Trump tweeted, “The word TARIFF is a beautiful word indeed,” as he proceeded to impose 10–50 percent tariffs on steel and aluminum and a wide array of Chinese goods. He has now doubled down and called for a universal 10 percent tariff on all foreign‐​produced goods. Although conservatism has been the political movement supporting free trade for decades, a number of self‐​styled conservatives are now abandoning this long‐​held conservative principle and are finding common cause with both Trump and the majority of protectionist Democrats on the issue. They shouldn’t, and their arguments in doing so are unpersuasive.

National Security and Protectionism

The number‐​one argument proffered to support protectionism is one based on national defense. After all, even Adam Smith admitted that national defense considerations were, of necessity, one of the exceptions to the free trade rule. However, from my personal experience of serving 16 years in Congress, I know firsthand how often bad policy is wrapped in the cloak of national defense.

When Trump unilaterally imposed his steel and aluminum tariffs in 2018, he did so under the authority of Section 232 of the misnamed Trade Expansion Act of 1962. To exercise that authority requires a finding that the imports in question threaten to impair national security. However, in the same year that the tariffs were imposed, James Mattis, then secretary of defense, noted that only 3 percent of US production of steel and aluminum were actually needed for our armed forces. That begged the question of how, then, steel and aluminum tariffs were justified for everything from automobiles to beverage cans. Do some truly believe that a Toyota 4Runner or a can of Heineken beer threaten our national security?

Another example of the argument occurred during debate of the annual National Defense Authorization Act (NDAA). An amendment was offered to effectively force the military to buy only US‐​made running shoes for new recruits. Are running shoes critical to our national defense? Incidentally, the amendment would have had the effect of benefiting only one company: New Balance. It was argued that many running shoes sold in America are manufactured in China. True, but they also continue to be manufactured in Taiwan, Indonesia, Finland, Italy, and Thailand as well. Should running shoes truly become critical to the defense of our nation? Could we not stockpile them when global prices are cheap? In a time of war, would we be unable to ramp up our own production of running shoes? After all, during World War II we showed that we could ramp up domestic production of aircraft from just over 2,000 in 1939 to 300,000 by 1945. Hard to believe we’re incapable of doing the same for running shoes or an array of other goods in the 21st century.

During debate on another NDAA bill, an amendment was offered to force the military to only buy stainless steel flatware from domestic sources. In opposing the amendment during debate, House Armed Services Chairman Mac Thornberry (R‑TX) remarked, “I just don’t think that the knives and forks we use qualify as vital national security.” What does negatively impact national security, though, is the needless depletion of national wealth that occurs every time the government fails to buy the best product at the most economical price.

Washington undoubtedly has legitimate concerns over supply chain reliance on China for products with a clear national security nexus. But many companies are already in the process, or have completed, a reengineering or relocation of their supply chains, and with additional conservative tax and regulatory policies, even more would do so. Importantly, there remains a whole host of export controls, foreign direct investment approvals, and defense procurement requirements to help meet the threat that China poses. When it comes to our national defense, clearly the Trump administration’s tariffs didn’t mute China’s saber rattling, its defense buildup, or its incursions into the South China Sea to threaten Taiwan.

As an aside, it needs to be noted that, in almost all respects, the tariffs imposed on Chinese goods by the Trump administration failed. The trade deficit, which remains a most misleading statistic but one favored by the former president, actually worsened during the Trump administration. Furthermore, tariffs proved to be a two‐​way street—as they usually do. Just ask the Midwest farmers who suffered massive losses from retaliatory tariffs from China and had to be bailed out with $28 billion of subsidies from the US taxpayer. Finally, it could not be clearer that the tariffs not only had no impact on weakening China’s military, but they also clearly had no impact on China’s human rights abuses or its carbon footprint.

More often than not, the national defense argument for protectionism is unjustified and should never become a pretext for the abandonment of free trade in favor of industrial policy, corporate welfare, and protectionism. These all harm economic growth and innovation and consequently harm our national defense.

Additionally, although trade does not guarantee peace—Russia’s gruesome invasion of Ukraine even though the two nations have a fair amount of two‐​way trade, for example—there is clear evidence that trade ties tend to reduce armed conflict between countries. This is consistent with what pro‐​market Enlightenment philosophers argued. Beginning in the aftermath of World War II, the United States used trade as a tool to enhance national security. It has been nearly 80 years since major world powers engaged in a major war—a period of relative peace that has coincided with the establishment of the US‐​led global trading system.

Likewise, trade can be an immense tool for American soft power. It helps spread American values and it enriches allies. In the early 1990s, Mexico was facing a policy choice: it could either continue down the path of protectionism and heavy government intervention, or it could move “toward decentralized, democratic capitalism.” The George H. W. Bush and Bill Clinton administrations understood that by better integrating the Mexican economy into the United States’ economy, NAFTA could nudge Mexico away from the false allure of socialism. On top of the economic benefits of NAFTA, the agreement was a foreign policy success. Although certainly not perfect, and despite some recent backsliding, Mexico today is more committed to binding and predictable international trade and investment rules than it was in the 1980s and early 1990s.

Too often trade is viewed as weakening America’s national security when in fact it’s usually the opposite.

Trade, the Working Class, and Domestic Manufacturing

Another prominent argument offered by self‐​styled conservatives is that free trade somehow hurts the working class. Conservatives undoubtedly consider the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017 (TCJA) to be the crowning achievement from when Republicans last governed. Yet many who heralded its pro‐​growth tax relief for working families turned around and supported tax increases on these very same families in the form of tariffs.

Countless studies have shown that almost all the costs of the tariffs initiated under the Trump administration were borne by consumers and businesses. At worst, these costs may have offset most of American households’ average savings from the TCJA. For example, the cost of a washing machine increased an average of $86 just months after tariffs were imposed on them. According to the American Action Forum, all those tariffs combined have now increased consumer costs approximately $51 billion a year. Some tax cut. To make matters worse, the Tax Foundation calculates, based on current levels of imports, that Trump’s universal 10 percent tariff proposal represents a whopping $300 billion tax increase. Just when did tax increases become popular among conservatives?

Today, most blue‐​collar workers work in services, not manufacturing, and their greatest concern is not the loss of their job due to foreign competition, it is the loss of buying power from a paycheck that has shrunk in the face of historic inflation. I doubt many so‐​called elites shop at Walmart, but many working people certainly do. If a customer buys a Zebco fishing rod there it has been produced in China, and if they pick up a pair of Cowboy Cut Wrangler jeans, they’ll likely have come from Bangladesh. Although Walmart doesn’t like to advertise the fact, it remains the nation’s largest importer, with its shelves stocked with tons of foreign‐​produced goods that help working families make ends meet. Tariffs wouldn’t bring back manufacturing jobs that produce fishing rods or blue jeans; they’d only make those products more expensive.

Closely related to the working‐​class harm argument is the loss of manufacturing jobs argument that others refer to as a “hollowing out” of the industrial heartland. Indeed, manufacturing employment as a percentage of the workforce has decreased dramatically over the past several decades. But contrary to popular belief, those jobs have not been lost to hamburger‐​flipping jobs but instead to transportation, warehousing, construction, health care, tech, communications, finance, and other service‐​oriented parts of our economy—industries that benefit from open trade and whose jobs pay far more than those in low‐​skill manufacturing. America’s comparative advantages in these industries is one of the reasons why we are the world’s number‐​one exporter of services and continuously run a services trade surplus.

The dominant factor in the loss of domestic manufacturing jobs is not foreign competition but instead productivity. For example, according to the American Iron and Steel Institute, it took 10.1 hours to produce a ton of steel in 1980; today it takes only 1.5 hours. There may be fewer manufacturing workers today, but because of productivity gains, they are better compensated. According to the Center for Strategic and International Studies, the median income of the remaining US blue‐​collar manufacturing jobs has increased 50 percent in real inflation‐​adjusted terms between 1960 and 2019.

The reality is that tariffs harm most manufacturing jobs. Relatively open trade is vital for manufacturing and our defense industrial base. As the Cato Institute’s Scott Lincicome and Alfredo Carrillo Obregon document, around half of all goods imported are in fact intermediate goods, raw materials, and capital equipment used for domestic manufacturing. For example, many pipeline manufacturing companies import specialty casing that is necessary for oil and gas pipelines. Taxing these imports hurts workers at these companies or, if the higher costs are passed on, their energy‐​producing customers. How ironic for any conservative to call for an “all of the above” energy policy (one that supports the development and deployment of every form of energy) yet support making hydrocarbons more difficult and expensive to produce.

We could strengthen domestic manufacturing, the defense industrial base, and our energy sector by unilaterally eliminating tariffs on intermediate inputs, raw materials, and capital equipment. Doing that would truly put America first.

Trade, Family, and Community

Trade makes the necessities of life cheaper and more abundant for families. Walking through a grocery store reveals that a lot of our everyday food items are imported from around the world. This raises real incomes for Americans by increasing their purchasing power. Indeed, according to recent research from the Peterson Institute for International Economics, reduced friction in international transactions since the end of World War II—from trade liberalization and improvements in transportation and technology—increased US gross domestic product by $2.6 trillion in 2022 dollars, or about $7,800 per person and $19,500 per household. A 2016 study from two economists estimates that trade particularly benefited low‐​income consumers, who spend more of their income on items that were traded, including manufactured goods and food.

Although the gains over the last 75 years have been significant, there is more work to be done. Consider a family outfitting their kids to go back to school in the fall. As Bryan Riley of the National Taxpayers Union recently noted, backpacks face a 17.6 percent tariff and rulers face a 13.6 percent tariff; meanwhile, blue jeans face an 8.4 percent tariff and shoes face an average tariff of 10.8 percent. Eliminating these tariffs on basic family necessities would raise real incomes of American families.

Likewise, trade benefits communities and civil society. Because of relatively open trade, we can consume more for less and, as a result, we can work fewer hours, which means that it frees up time to participate in activities that build community, whether it’s volunteering, going to church, or coaching tee‐​ball. (The bats and tees are probably imported too.)

Moreover, although the media focuses on midwestern cities that hurt by import competition, there are countless stories about cities and towns that were once hurt by imports but that now thrive, in large part because of international trade. Take the border areas in Texas. They once had large concentrations of low value‐​added manufacturing. But according to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, “NAFTA, along with other market forces and technological change, created different jobs in Texas as low value‐​added manufacturing jobs were lost and as trade and investment increased. Border cities went on to gain far more employment than what they lost amid increased imports from Canada and Mexico and shifting production between the countries.” Indeed, economic integration has been enormously beneficial for Texas. The same Dallas Fed report notes, “A 10 percent increase in manufacturing on the Mexican side of the border increases employment 2.2 percent in Brownsville, 2.8 percent in El Paso, 4.6 percent in Laredo and 6.6 percent in McAllen.”

Conservatives have long argued that family and communities are the bedrocks of a free and prosperous society. Freer trade complements both. It’s surely not a cure‐​all for what ails our culture, but it helps. And the things that actually have hollowed out many American families and communities go way beyond economics. The underlying causes lie more in the realm of cultural changes and bad public policies, especially in the area of welfare. Tariffs can’t fix problems that trade didn’t cause.

Protectionism, Bureaucracy, and Rent Seeking

One of the great rallying cries of many conservatives remains “Drain the swamp!” But after the previous administration imposed its tariffs, it immediately empowered hundreds of Washington bureaucrats at the Department of Commerce and the Office of the US Trade Representative to grant individual waivers from these very same tariffs under what can at best be described as an opaque process with discretionary standards. As one company officer of a small pipeline manufacturer put it, “[Applying for a waiver] is a nightmare, like dealing with a lawyer and the IRS at the same time.” A schedule of tariffs doesn’t drain the swamp; it instead fills it with a cadre of well‐​connected lawyers, lobbyists, and special interests to work a system run by Washington bureaucrats.

It is difficult to comprehend how one can proudly wave the Gadsden flag, proclaiming “Don’t Tread on Me,” and then seemingly turn around and remark, “But go ahead ‘swamp,’ take away my freedom and choose for me which products I’m allowed to buy.”

Others charge that global trade is inherently antithetical to American interests. Notwithstanding being polysyllabic, “globalization” is now treated as a four‐​letter word. Although “globalization” is not clearly defined, the word conveys to many not just a loss of American jobs but a loss of American interests, prestige, identity, and perhaps most importantly, a loss of American sovereignty. Undoubtedly what comes out of the vast array of international organizations and forums in which the United States participates has helped fuel these fears. Even if it is not harmful, US membership in many of these may be of dubious value to some conservatives. As one former Congressman said in private conversation, “Why do we continue to pay the UN to insult us when they’d likely do it for free?” Conservatives legitimately question whether it is truly in America’s interest to participate in global conferences and organizations such as the United Nation’s Climate Change Conference, the Inter‐​American Development Bank, and the International Trade Union Confederation.

What can’t be questioned, though, is that Article I, Section 1 of the Constitution still reads, “All legislative Powers herein granted shall be vested in a Congress of the United States …” (emphasis added.) What can’t be questioned, though, is that Article II, Section 2 still reads in part, “[The President] shall have Power, by and with the Advice and Consent of the Senate, to make Treaties, provided two thirds of the Senators present concur.” Whatever treaties we enter into, and whatever commitments we make to other countries or international organizations, are an exercise of US sovereignty, not the loss of such. And what we enter into, we can exit. The United States unilaterally terminated its first treaty in 1798 and has done so on many occasions since.

No nation‐​state or international body can compel us to do anything without our consent. Should we choose to walk away from an agreement or treaty, the other party or parties may, of course, then choose to treat us in ways in which we prefer to not be treated. But again, they simply cannot sanction us with fines or loss of property without our consent. Our elected officials may agree to be bound by certain international rules or obligations whenever they decide the mutual pledges of other nations are in our national interest. But whenever “We the People” disagree with those decisions, we have the opportunity to unbind ourselves by electing either a new president, a new Congress, or both.

When it comes to our trade relations, the WTO is singled out for usurping US sovereignty. It doesn’t. It is simply a voluntary organization of trading nations attempting to come to consensus on accepted trade rules. Once rules are agreed upon, the organization attempts to arbitrate and it makes rulings by interpreting those rules. The WTO itself doesn’t initiate action and has no ability to enforce dispute settlement rulings other than by authorizing a complaining (winning) member government to deny a responding (losing) member government some of the benefits of membership. The WTO is a most imperfect organization that is in constant need of reform. But it usurps no US sovereignty, and we have more global trade benefiting the United States because of it.

Conclusion

In the final analysis, the most important reason anyone calling themselves a conservative should remain committed to trade has nothing to do with economics. Instead, it has everything to do with securing “the Blessings of Liberty to ourselves and our Posterity,” something for which our Founders risked their lives, fortunes, and sacred honor. Trade should not be viewed as a matter of discretionary foreign policy or a lever to promote economic nationalism. And although the data and historic evidence is overwhelmingly convincing that trade leads to greater economic growth, ultimately trade remains an issue of personal freedom, specifically economic freedom and its relation to private property. To “Buy American” should not be a matter of where one buys. For conservatives, it should instead be a matter of how one buys, and that how is with freedom of choice. If the conservative movement is to still stand for freedom of speech, freedom of enterprise, and freedom to bear arms, as a matter of principle it must firmly and unequivocally stand for freedom of trade.

To read the full essay published by the Cato Institute, click here.

 

The Progressive Case for Globalization

Introduction

Globalization has transformed the world. Centuries ago, it brought exotic spices and wares to distant corners of the globe. More recently, it has allowed us to work, see our families, and live our lives despite the disruptions caused by a once‐​in‐​a‐​lifetime pandemic. Trade in particular is a major component of globalization, which has lifted over a billion people out of poverty, made us more productive, and contributed to peace. Despite this, globalization and trade are under attack.

US Trade Representative Katherine Tai argued that the traditional approach to trade, focused on economic efficiency, has contributed to “a race to the bottom.” Meanwhile, President Biden has been beating the drum for his Made in America approach, even if it harms ties with our allies. Defending President Biden’s “Invest in America” agenda, Heather Boushey, member of the president’s Council of Economic Advisers, stated that “the global trading system has not always been fair, not always delivered the promised benefits to our citizens, [and] too often favored large corporate interests over workers’ interests.” The administration has thus called for a “new Washington consensus” but still has not answered the question posed by Jake Sullivan: “How does trade fit into our international economic policy, and what problems is it seeking to solve?”

What is striking about these statements is how far removed they are from traditional progressive views on trade and globalization, namely, that domestic and international prosperity are interlinked, that trade institutions support the rule of law, and that globalization is a tool for advancing well‐​being among the poorest. Trade has thus been peripheral to the Biden administration’s foreign economic policy. The shift in Washington toward favoring protectionist policies over trade openness is not only bad policy, but for progressives now calling for a new approach to trade, it also cuts against the very goals they are trying to achieve.

Tariff Liberalization as a Progressive Project

Economic turmoil and global conflict during the first half of the 20th century prompted a bold rethink of the international order. President Franklin Delano Roosevelt led the charge, overcoming fractured views on trade within his own party. The pragmatic and strategic vision of his secretary of state, Cordell Hull, helped him recognize the necessity of international economic cooperation to generate peace and prosperity at home and abroad. Roosevelt saw firsthand the devastating economic and social consequences of the Great Depression and acknowledged the role of trade barriers in deepening the crisis.

In a 1936 speech in Buenos Aires, Roosevelt criticized countries for their “attempts to be self‐​sufficient,” which “led to failing standards for their people and to ever‐​increasing loss of the democratic ideals in a mad race to pile armament on armament.” He called these policies “suicidal” and lamented that despite the suffering they caused, “many … people have come to believe with despair that the price of war seems less than the price of peace.”

The United States was no stranger to such policies. As post–World War I reconstruction was underway, European producers reemerged in the international market, fueling competition as they increased their exports. In the United States, amid a backdrop of economic uncertainty, many advocated for restrictive trade remedies that eventually culminated in the 1930 Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act, which led to an average tariff increase of 20 percent. Though originally intended to shield the agricultural sector from foreign competition through targeted tariffs, congressional logrolling greatly expanded the scope of the act to cover a broad range of products.

Unsurprisingly, its implementation sparked retaliatory measures from US trading partners, which included tariffs and quotas on products primarily imported from American producers, as well as widespread boycotts of American goods. While American exporters faced higher barriers to market access abroad, American consumers saw increases of between 4 and 6 percent in the relative price of imports, further reducing purchasing power and raising the cost of living. Though the tariffs did not bring about the Great Depression, economic historian Douglas Irwin notes that they contributed to both a “severe deterioration in trade relations in the early 1930s” and a global embrace of trade protectionism.

On the campaign trail in 1933, Roosevelt lambasted President Herbert Hoover and Republican leaders for the Smoot–Hawley tariff, saying that “President Hoover probably should have known that this tariff would raise havoc with any plans that he might have had to stimulate foreign markets,” and that the tariff was “the road to ruin, if we keep on it!” Retaliation from US trading partners was a major concern, making it difficult to sell products even to “logical customers, your neighbors across the border.” Roosevelt had another idea, which came from Hull, for “a tariff policy based on reason … a tariff policy based in large part upon the simple principle of profitable exchange, arrived at through negotiated tariff, with benefit to each Nation.” While Roosevelt was primarily concerned with economic stability in the United States, he was aware that this could not be achieved alone. In fact, he quickly recognized the symbiotic relationship between domestic recovery and the health of global trade.

The challenge, however, was that FDR lacked the authority to reduce trade barriers because the Constitution vests Congress with the power to regulate foreign commerce. Roosevelt and Hull thus jointly urged Congress to adopt the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934 (RTAA), which, once passed, would empower the executive branch to negotiate tariff reduction agreements based on the principles of reciprocity and mutual benefit. Roosevelt explained that “by reducing our own tariff in conjunction with the reduction by other countries of their trade barriers, we create jobs, get more for our money, and improve the standard of living of every American consumer.” Furthermore, by increasing the authority granted to the executive branch, the RTAA reduced the impact of parochial interests in trade policy, since the president represented a national constituency.

Though many sensitive domestic industries retained trade protections, the RTAA marked a turning point in US trade policy. Not only did trade critics consider it to be fairly managed, it also found support among 71 percent of Americans. That did not mean its renewal did not face opposition in Congress, but as the United States entered the Second World War, sensible tariff policy became an instrument beyond domestic economic recovery and would serve as the foundation for a new international economic order guided by pragmatism, cooperation, and shared prosperity.

International Peace, Alliances, and the Rule of Law

Domestic economic recovery was not the only motivation for transforming the global economy defined by a liberalized trade regime. Rather, trade proponents strongly believed that deep economic integration would boost international peacebuilding and result in a freer, fairer world.

This idea is not new. In 1795, Immanuel Kant outlined how a constitution for civil law among nations could overcome the law of nature and create the conditions for perpetual peace. A key component of this was universal hospitality, which could make, among other things, “commerce with native inhabitants possible” so that “distant parts of the world can establish with one another peaceful relations that will eventually become matters of public law, and the human race can gradually be brought closer and closer to a cosmopolitan constitution.” The freedom to engage in commerce and avoid plunder was thus considered an important aspect of establishing a peaceful international community.

While the academic debate over the pacifying effects of international trade is ongoing, scholars agree that trade is an important variable that contributes to peace, though they place different weight on the explanatory power of liberal philosophy versus structural factors, such as liberal institutions, and the conditions under which the relationship is most salient. Reflecting on his own experiences, Hull described his personal realization of the idea that trade could lead to peace:

When the war came in 1914, I was very soon impressed with two points. The first was its terrific commercial impact on the United States. I saw that you could not separate the idea of commerce from the idea of war and peace.… And the second was that wars were often largely caused by economic rivalry conducted unfairly. I thereupon came to believe that if we could eliminate this bitter economic rivalry, if we could increase commercial exchanges among nations over lowered trade and tariff barriers and remove unnatural obstructions to trade, we would go a long way toward eliminating war itself.

Hull’s recounting provides further evidence for the argument that managing economic security concerns became a central issue for the architects of the postwar international order. One such way to address these concerns was through a framework of rules that would lower barriers to trade and provide for the peaceful settlement of disputes. The first step to achieve this was the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), which helped facilitate open trade relations based on the principles of reciprocity, nondiscrimination, transparency, and enforceability. At the launch of the GATT negotiations, Roosevelt made the case before Congress for why US participation was so important, noting that “the purpose of the whole effort is to eliminate economic warfare, to make practical international cooperation effective on as many fronts as possible, and so to lay the economic basis for the secure and peaceful world we all desire.”

By establishing a rules‐​based system, the GATT prioritized a predictable trade environment that would prevent the resurgence of the protectionist policies that worsened the economic instability and political conflicts of the first half of the 20th century. However, the GATT needed to be updated and expanded through successive rounds of negotiations that moved beyond simple tariff barriers. Another Democratic president was responsible for one of the most important rounds of GATT negotiations, which was eventually named after him—the Kennedy Round.

Prior to starting those talks, John F. Kennedy had secured authorization from Congress for additional tariff cuts up to 50 percent under the Trade Expansion Act of 1962. Upon signing the legislation, Kennedy remarked that “this act recognizes, fully and completely, that we cannot protect our economy by stagnating behind tariff walls, but that the best protection possible is a mutual lowering of tariff barriers among friendly nations so that all may benefit from a free flow of goods.” Kennedy argued that expanding trade would not only strengthen the US economic position but also bolster US alliances and, in doing so, help counter the threat posed by communism. He thus called the Trade Expansion Act “an important new weapon to advance the cause of freedom.”

International institutions were central to advancing these goals and supported a strong belief in the centrality of the rule of law and fairness that undergirds the progressivism movement. In a 1942 radio address, Hull explained why Americans should support US involvement in the war, stating that “liberty under law is an essential requirement of progress.” Liberty, to Hull, was “more than a matter of political rights.” In fact, he argued that the United States had “learned from bitter experience that to be truly free, men must have, as well, economic freedom and economic security.” Extending that internationally, Hull argued for “cooperative action under common agreement,” which “will enable each to increase the effectiveness of its own national effort.” Fifty‐​two years later, to mark the signing of the Uruguay Round Agreements Act that established the World Trade Organization (WTO), President Bill Clinton also made the case for “a fair and increasingly open world trading system that allows the free market to work and rewards the most productive people in the world,” as a means to “restore stability to the lives of the working people of our country.” Economic security at home, it was understood, required international institutions based on the principle of fair competition, which would facilitate access to economic opportunities.

An important way to assure fairness is to have a system of rules that applies equally to all and a means of recourse when those rules are violated. At the WTO, that has been the dispute settlement system, which allows countries to peacefully resolve trade disputes among themselves. What is truly amazing about this system is that even the smallest countries have access to it, and throughout most of the organization’s history, no country has seen itself as above the law.

A rules‐​based trading system was therefore always a precondition for economic interdependence that would be fair and accessible to all. Today, economic interdependence is still a core principle of liberal internationalism, though in Washington policy circles it has become less valued over time. Part of this stems from a loss of confidence in the rules‐​based order. President Biden’s national security adviser, Jake Sullivan, questioned “the premise that economic integration would make nations more responsible and open, and that the global order would be more peaceful and cooperative,” arguing that “Russia’s invasion of Ukraine underscored the risks of overdependence.” Tai shares this view, when in response to a question about how Russia’s invasion of Ukraine had upended the accepted wisdom of trade promoting peace, she said, “Peace is probably more necessary for prosperity than prosperity is for peace.”

Each of these arguments veers far from the progressive views toward trade and interdependence held by Roosevelt (whose portrait hangs above the fireplace in President Biden’s Oval Office), as well as other progressives. They also fail to understand the nuance in the trade‐​promotes‐​peace literature by arguing that the presence of any conflict disproves the theory that economic integration reduces the frequency and scope of conflict. Furthermore, as political scientist Daniel Drezner points out, complex interdependence made it difficult for Russia’s closest geopolitical ally, China, to provide strong public support for the war in Ukraine. In fact, he argues that China’s links to the global economy and Western countries in particular curbed its behavior by tipping the cost–benefit analysis to favor adopting a less prominent role in the war. The Russia–Ukraine war thus reveals that while interdependence does not eliminate all security concerns, the liberal international order still effectively constrains aggressive foreign policy behavior and fosters collective responses. This is precisely why, in his famous address at American University in 1963, Kennedy remarked that “even the most hostile nations can be relied upon to accept and keep those treaty obligations, and only those treaty obligations, which are in their own interests.” A material interest in accessing markets can thus moderate a country’s behavior.

The loss of faith in the power of interdependence as a restraint and the benefits of a system based on rules appears to be the new consensus in Washington, perhaps best executed by former president Donald Trump. Under his administration, the United States launched a series of trade wars that not only resulted in significant economic harm at home and retaliation that soured relations with our closest trading partners but also undermined the rules‐​based trading system. Though President Biden has made important strides in improving relations with our allies, on trade, he has largely preserved, and defended, some of Trump’s most controversial policy actions.

For example, when the metals tariffs that were applied for alleged national security concerns were found to violate international trade rules, Adam Hodge, who was then a spokesperson for the US Trade Representative, denounced the ruling, saying that “the United States strongly rejects the flawed interpretation” of the rules and that “issues of national security cannot be reviewed in WTO dispute settlement.” To make the US objection clear, he went on to say, “We do not intend to remove the Section 232 duties as a result of these disputes.” What is interesting about the Biden administration’s position is that in saying its actions are above the law, the United States has now established a slippery slope whereby other countries can claim national security interests as cover for trade protectionism.

The US approach to trade has shifted far from its progressive roots in another important way as well. The spirit of cooperation and need for predictability that underscored the postwar institution‐​building efforts are also under threat, not just with adversaries but with allies too. Discussing the sunset review of the United States‐​Canada‐​Mexico Agreement, Tai stated that “the whole point” of the negotiations “is to maintain a certain level of discomfort, which may involve a certain level of uncertainty.” During the Trump administration, uncertainty was a driving strategy of trade policy.

The problem with uncertainty, however, is that it breeds confusion, economic disruption, loss of trust, and hesitancy over making commitments. This is the direct opposite of what motivated the architects of the modern international trading system and its most steadfast champion, the United States. The last expression of those progressive ideals was shared by former US Trade Representative Michael Froman in his exit memo, where he wrote: “Through our trade policy, we bolster our partners and allies, lead efforts to write the rules of the road for fair trade among partners, and promote broad‐​based development. Trade done right is essential for our economy here at home and for America’s position in the world.” In contrast, US policymakers today have increasingly embraced a more zero‐​sum logic and thus failed to appreciate the importance of leading by example on trade and other foreign economic policies.

Tackling Poverty and Promoting Shared Prosperity

Though many advocates of trade protectionism today often point to levels of global inequality, stalled development, and middle‐​class stagnation as justifications for de‐​globalization, the evidence paints a more positive picture of globalization. In fact, looking at indicators such as life expectancy, infant mortality, literacy, and living standards, the story of the era of globalization is one of considerable progress and declining inequality.

From 1990 to 2019, the share of the global population living below the poverty line—set at $2.15 per day based on 2017 prices—decreased from 38.01 percent to 8.98 percent. Economist Kimberly Clausing explains that within China alone, “the share of the population living in poverty fell from 88 percent of the population to 2 percent of the population between 1980 and 2012,” suggesting that a billion people were lifted out of extreme poverty due to China’s economic opening. The negative correlation between trade openness and poverty levels is difficult to dispute, especially considering that regions with the most stagnant economic growth are those that maintain high tariff barriers and have therefore seen slow trade growth, such as sub‐​Saharan Africa. In addition to reducing poverty, expanded trade led to increased gross domestic product (GDP) growth. Economists Gary Hufbauer and Megan Hogan estimate that without post–World War II trade liberalization, US GDP would have been $2.6 trillion lower in 2022, at $22.9 trillion instead of $25.5 trillion, averaging to welfare gains of $19,500 per household in 2022. These gains from trade have broadly benefited consumers and reduced inequality. The Cato Institute’s Chelsea Follett explains that this time period has also witnessed considerable progress toward raising living standards worldwide.

While small changes to tariff rates may appear inconsequential, the WTO estimates that universal withdrawals from free trade agreements and increases in most‐​favored‐​nation tariff rates would decrease real income by 0.3 percent and 0.8 percent within three years, respectively. The 6 percent increase in food prices in the United Kingdom following Brexit offers a potent example of this effect, when the cost of living increased 50 percent more for low‐​income households compared to high‐​income households. Critically, these costs were not evenly distributed, as lower‐​income households spend a higher portion of their income on imported items than high‐​income households.

Worsening this disproportionate effect is the fact that trade barriers raise the cost of goods and services and reduce the choices available to consumers. Recently, the 2024 Economic Report to the President highlighted that US imports from China were “accompanied by a substantial fall in US consumer prices, with disproportionate benefits accruing to low‐ and middle‐​income households because they have higher shares of tradable goods like food and apparel in their consumption baskets.” In the United States, it’s particularly striking that cheaper consumer goods typically maintain higher tariff rates than equivalent luxury products.

Ed Gresser, vice president and director for trade and global markets at the Progressive Policy Institute, identified this trend across the US tariff schedule and found, for example, that the tariff rate placed on steel spoons is five times higher than the rate placed on silver spoons. Similarly, while a cashmere sweater has a 4 percent tariff rate, wool sweaters have a 17 percent rate, and acrylic sweaters have a 32 percent tariff rate. This makes the US tariff schedule a regressive tax whereby low‐​income households are not only spending a higher portion of their income on imported items, but they are also paying a higher average tariff rate on those purchased goods. A growth in protectionist measures would exacerbate these inequities.

However, since the gains from trade are often diffused throughout the economy, they can often go unnoticed and are given less attention than trade costs, which are often concentrated. As a case in point, the “China Shock” serves as a common talking point for critics of globalization, even though the findings of the famous study that coined the term have been strongly contested.

In placing so much emphasis on concentrated and marginal direct employment losses, globalization’s critics also fail to see the widespread economic benefits of trade through greater competition with foreign producers, which results in lower prices for consumers and limits domestic firms’ ability to pursue monopolies, as Clausing explains in her book, Open: The Progressive Case for Free Trade, Immigration, and Global Capital. On the other hand, Clausing also calculates that “protectionist measures cost consumers as a group, on average, over $500,000 per job saved” through added taxes caused by higher tariffs. In some industries this cost is more extreme; according to economist Anne Krueger, “it is estimated that the annual cost of one job ‘saved’ in the steel industry is about $900,000.” These unemployment‐​based evaluations also ignore that lower tariff rates reduce the costs of intermediate goods for domestic manufacturers, which in turn leads to greater production capacity and hiring ability. Final made‐​in‐​America products are thus cheaper because of these foreign intermediate inputs, increasing their market competitiveness.

Clausing thus analogizes the trade shock to technology shocks: While advances in technology can reduce the demand for some jobs, they simultaneously increase productivity and efficiency, create many new job opportunities, and benefit everyday users. It would be unusual to come across someone who would argue that the internet should not have been broadly adopted for the sake of conserving a small portion of jobs. This is not to suggest that these shocks are not serious policy concerns; rather, it is intended to demonstrate that imposing protectionist measures to save jobs will fail to achieve the desired effect and instead will reduce economic growth and impose widespread costs. Broadly speaking, these negative externalities should be remedied through more robust public policy instead of trade restrictions to assist Americans in adjusting to economic disruptions.

As one of the report’s authors, Gordon Hanson, later remarked in Foreign Affairs, though the China Shock “hurt many US workers and their communities … so, too, have automation, the Great Recession, and the COVID-19 pandemic. And because the scarring effects of job losses are the same whether imports, robots, or a virus is responsible, responses to the damage should not depend on the identity of the culprit.” He therefore argued that protectionist measures “will do little to help workers who are already hurting or to help others avoid a similar fate” and that instead, the president “should establish targeted domestic programs that protect workers from the downsides of globalization.”

Though trade generally acts as a positive force, challenges persist. The economic disruptions and global health crisis caused by the COVID-19 pandemic drove many countries, including the United States, to grow wary of globalization, leaning away from international trade cooperation in favor of a more protectionist and at times fragmented system. However, the presumption that the optimal solution to these global challenges lies solely in unilateral or regional action is flawed. As WTO director‐​general Ngozi Okonjo‐​Iweala noted in the World Trade Report 2023, “a retreat from economic integration would roll back recent development gains, make it harder for countries to grow their way out of poverty, and harm future economic prospects for the poorest people the most.” In other words, fragmentation would only exacerbate existing challenges.

The World Trade Report instead advocated for addressing the world’s most pressing challenges through greater global openness, integration, and cooperation, contingent on the reform of the international trading system. This approach, termed “re‐​globalization,” aims to integrate more economies into the global trading system and to promote a more equitable, transparent, and reliable trading framework. As President Barack Obama once stated, “globalization is a fact,” and while the United States can’t “build a wall” around globalization, he said, “what we can do is to shape how that process of global integration proceeds so that it’s increasing opportunity for ordinary people.”

The United States has long shaped that process. In fact, it was American leadership in the global economy that established the WTO, which President Clinton described as “a victory for a couple of simple ideas.” Essentially, “the idea that America can lead in the 21st century, that we need not fear competition, that we want our neighbors to do better than they have been doing, and when they do better, we will do better.” Though the belief that a rising tide can lift all boats is no longer in vogue in Washington, it has been a driving force for US engagement in the world economy and has contributed to a healthier, wealthier, and more stable world.

Conclusion

US leadership in the global economy is needed now more than ever, yet there is no need to rethink the entire trading system. The blueprint is well known, and as this essay shows, the driving force behind the modern trading system is deeply rooted in American values. Many progressives have called this system unfair. No institution is perfect, and it is true that the WTO and US trade agreements as we have known them would benefit from reform. However, their critics have lost sight of the very real benefits globalization and trade have provided and have also forgotten the progressive ideas that helped shape the international trading system after the Second World War. That system has not only reduced poverty but has also promoted shared prosperity, at home and abroad. Progressives would do well to remember these achievements and their important part in securing them.

To read the full essay published by the Cato Institute, click here.

The post The Conservative Case & The Progressive Case for Globalization appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Designing a New Paradigm in Global Trade /atp-research/new-paradigm/ Mon, 20 May 2024 18:10:21 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=46041 How a successful Global Arrangement on Sustainable Steel and Aluminum could function while delivering maximum benefits to workers and the environment.   Introduction and summary The Global Arrangement on Sustainable...

The post Designing a New Paradigm in Global Trade appeared first on WITA.

]]>
How a successful Global Arrangement on Sustainable Steel and Aluminum could function while delivering maximum benefits to workers and the environment.

 

Introduction and summary

The Global Arrangement on Sustainable Steel and Aluminum (GASSA)—a proposed agreement to increase trade in steel and aluminum produced in a way that emits lower greenhouse gas emissions—may be the most ambitious trade initiative pursued by the Biden administration and offers a template to move beyond the traditional neoliberal approach to free trade. Much has been written on why GASSA would be a game-changer for U.S. trade policy, including by the authors of this report. To date, however, there has been little exploration of how GASSA, or an expanded GASSA-like arrangement that includes more trading partners, would work—until now.

This report describes key decision points and makes recommendations about implementing a trade arrangement that affords preferential market access on the basis of carbon intensity and creates a common approach to address nonmarket overcapacity. These include: 1) preconditions that members of the arrangement should commit to before joining, including respect for high standard labor rights, a coordinated strategy to addressing overcapacity, and a commitment to broad industrial decarbonization; 2) a tariff structure that advantages low-carbon steel and aluminum imported from like-minded partners over dirty imports from nonmarket economies such as China; 3) the use of benchmarks, which grow more ambitious over time, to assess what counts as “low-carbon”; and 4) reforms to the nation’s customs system so that U.S. officials can distinguish between low- and high-carbon goods at the border.

The United States has gone from a climate laggard to a climate leader in just a few short years. Key to unlocking this progress has been moving past a neoliberal approach that lets market actors decide where and how—and how dirty—to produce goods and services and moving toward using a green industrial policy that can restructure production at the speed and scale needed to meet the United States’ commitments under the Paris Agreement.

This new industrial strategy is being executed through several tracks. First, the Inflation Reduction Act and the CHIPS and Science Act channel grants, loans, and tax credits to bring online a new supply of clean energy and manufactures, from goods from semiconductors and electric vehicles to green hydrogen and low-carbon steel. Second, the Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act creates demand for this new supply through public works programs using domestically produced, clean steel and other inputs. Third, an emerging international climate and trade strategy complements this domestic agenda by rewriting international rules that condition access to national markets on respecting the climate.

Among international climate strategies, GASSA is furthest along. Launched in October 2021 between the United States and the European Union, it would set up a trans-Atlantic arrangement that could eventually expand to a club of countries. Participating countries would agree to offer preferential market access based on carbon intensity, while also agreeing to joint actions to address the challenge of nonmarket practices in the steel and aluminum industries. The choice of these two metals is not accidental. They account for about 11 percent of global carbon dioxide emissions and nearly one-third of industrial emissions. Moreover, countries such as China have been flooding global markets with excess, dirty production, and as a result, the metals are already subject to extensive trade protection measures.

Although the United States, the European Union, and their industries share a common interest in greening and stabilizing steel and aluminum trade, progress on the negotiations has been frustratingly slow. The United States has made a number of proposals over two years of negotiations, but the European Union remained in a more passive and reactive mode. After missing a deadline in October 2023 for finishing these talks, both sides extended a relative “peace” on bilateral trade flows, allowing for more negotiation time.

The authors of this report have previously written about the historic opportunity that GASSA would present. To summarize, GASSA or a GASSA-like agreement would strengthen U.S.-EU coordination, helping to write the rules of 21st-century trade. However, no new timeline has been announced, and there are reasons to believe the European Union currently lacks sufficient motivation to come to a deal that meets the needs of the United States and of industries and workforces in both America and Europe.

While it is difficult to know exactly how the negotiations will unfold moving forward, the opportunity for the United States to create a new global trade paradigm that affords market access based on carbon-intensity and addresses nonmarket overcapacity is too important to abandon. The European Union’s Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism (CBAM) essentially means that the European Union will continue to be important in discussions over any GASSA-like arrangement, but it may be unwilling to make the compromises necessary for a cooperative approach to decarbonizing the metals trade. For that reason, these twin objectives could very well become the basis of negotiations with other ambitious trading partners and—if successful—could become the organizing principle for a global system looking for a new means to organize and manage trade relations. Indeed, in remarks at Columbia University on April 16, Special Presidential Envoy for Climate John Podesta suggested precisely this kind of expanded approach, calling for discussions with U.S. “partners and allies around the world, from the UK to Australia to the EU.”

This strategy is particularly interesting, as it turns the traditional neoliberal approach to trade on its head. No longer would the United States or other developed economies offer market access on the promise, or in the hope, that eventually trade would lead to alignment on standards for workers or the environment. GASSA or a GASSA-like agreement, rather, would ensure that standards come first, as a prerequisite  before a trading partner would benefit from preferential market access. Such a structure may start with steel and aluminum, given the sector’s unique trade exposure, but could easily encourage decarbonization and high standards in other sectors as well. This idea shares a strong sentiment with the comments made by Brazilian Finance Minister Fernando Haddad at a recent meeting with his G20 counterparts, where he called for a “new globalization” based on social and environmental principles.

The steel and aluminum sectors offer a few major advantages as a starting point for this type of innovative approach to trade. First, steel and aluminum are already subject to extensive trade controls globally. Second, likely participants have established environmental regulatory systems, including protocols for carbon accounting, which may reduce the administrative burden needed to make a tariff based on carbon intensity successful; as Podesta noted, developing common approaches to these accounting problems should be a major object of international cooperation. Third, the global steel and aluminum industries have been particularly affected by China’s nonmarket overcapacity, putting producers in market-based, high-standard countries and their workers at a disadvantage that has resulted in job losses and a decline in international competitiveness.

In the United States, steel production is often far less carbon intensive than production in China. GASSA or a GASSA-like agreement would thus do more than provide an incentive for steel producers to decarbonize: It would turn a carbon advantage into a meaningful market advantage that could facilitate additional investment in U.S. steel capacity and create goods jobs. A similar dynamic exists elsewhere, including in the European Union, Canada, the United Kingdom, Japan, South Korea, and Brazil—all potential partners in the creation of a GASSA-like structure.

Thus, while it is possible to envision a GASSA-like structure for other sectors, this report focuses on the design choices needed to move a steel and aluminum trade regime forward, either with the European Union or with other negotiating partners. The goal is to highlight the policy options that negotiators must consider in order to reach an agreement that is maximally beneficial to steel and aluminum workers and the economic and national security of both the United States and its partners as well as focuses on the global effort to address climate change.

 

Prerequisites to joining the global arrangement

Prerequisites to joining a GASSA-like structure are central to ensuring that a global arrangement can fulfill its objectives of conditioning market access on participants meeting ambitious climate and labor standards, as well as addressing overcapacity in the industry. This can ensure that proper, coordinated actions are taken to address the nonmarket practices of others and can reduce the risk of resource shuffling, i.e., producers simply exporting their cleaner products and selling locally their dirtier products without any actual movement toward decarbonization. Prerequisite commitments can also be used to advance the values of global arrangement participants related to labor rights, broader climate cooperation, and support for shared research and development (R&D). At least four types of threshold commitments should be required for joining the arrangement.

Labor rights

Global arrangement participants should meet certain labor rights requirements in their steel and aluminum sectors that go beyond merely passing labor laws—particularly if markets with a history of lax enforcement are allowed to join. A high-standard commitment to worker health and safety, appropriate pay, and support for unionization and collective bargaining, for example, could all be included in a prerequisite commitment for participants of the global arrangement. The Facility-Specific Rapid Response Mechanism in the United States-Mexico-Canada Agreement has been a successful tool for policing compliance with these labor standards, and negotiators should consider including a similar mechanism in the global arrangement as well.

Industrial decarbonization

As noted above, a feature of GASSA or a GASSA-like structure is the flexibility participants would have to adopt different kinds of domestic decarbonization measures to improve on the EU CBAM. Some countries, such as the United States, may prefer an approach that focuses on regulatory standards and subsidies. Others, such as the European Union, may prefer systems that are more focused on taxation or carbon pricing. The prerequisite standards should be sensitive to the fact that different members may have different political and legal constraints in approaching domestic decarbonization.

At the same time, the resource shuffling problem is most effectively addressed if participants agree on some broad benchmarks for domestic decarbonization. These could be framed in terms of results rather than the adoption of specific domestic measures. Still, the benchmarks would ensure that carbon-intensive production cannot just continue to thrive via domestic consumption.

Likewise, the importance of subsidies to the green transition creates a potential conflict among nations. Existing trade rules allow—and in some cases domestic law may require—countries to impose additional duties called “trade remedies” on subsidized imports. Arrangement participants should agree not to impose new countervailing duties (CVD)—a type of trade remedy imposed on subsidized imports—on steel or aluminum imported from another participant’s market if a subsidy that would otherwise be subject to CVD protection was provided to facilitate the decarbonization of metals production in their home market and the subsidy was not contingent on export. Failing to do so could eliminate the market access for green metals that the arrangement seeks to create.

Finally, it may make sense for markets agreeing to join the global arrangement to also commit to continuous improvement to decarbonize their industrial sectors outside the steel and aluminum sectors. Possible commitments could include financial or investment pledges or specific decarbonization targets linked to a country’s climate commitments.

A strategic approach to overcapacity

Participants in the global arrangement should coordinate their responses to steel and aluminum overcapacity. This is different than how to handle steel produced by markets outside the global arrangement. There should be a coordinated approach to trade enforcement, ensuring that steel and aluminum produced using nonmarket, illegal, or unfair subsidies does not compete with steel produced by market-based suppliers. This could, for example, take the form of an additional common tariff or even a ban on steel or aluminum produced in nonmarket economies, effectively creating new export opportunities for low-carbon steel produced in fellow GASSA markets to replace dirtier steel produced in China.

R&D collaboration

Participants in the global arrangement could agree to collaborate on joint R&D projects related to the decarbonization of steel and aluminum production as well as a common approach to broad deployment of decarbonization techniques and technologies across GASSA markets. While it will be important to maintain a clear market advantage for firms willing to develop and invest in the decarbonization of their output, there may be situations where joint or collaborative R&D can help the entire industry become more sustainable. Negotiators should consider identifying such opportunities and ensure that global arrangement participants work together to leverage them to maximum effect.

 

Decision points within GASSA or GASSA-like trade regime

The second, and perhaps most complicated, type of design questions in the development of GASSA or a GASSA-like structure involve the mechanics of how a tariff regime would work for those countries that have agreed to the prerequisite commitments and joined the arrangement. These include the following questions.

Who should be invited to join?

Initial negotiations were bilateral between the United States and the European Union, but the United States should consider inviting others, including the United Kingdom, Canada, South Korea, Japan, Australia, Norway, and Brazil, to join the existing talks. Moreover, if the European Union remains reluctant to agree to such terms, the United States should begin talks on a GASSA-like agreement with one or more of these other potential partners, recognizing that any potential negotiating partner(s) must share a similar level of ambition toward climate, market principles, and core labor rights.

From an economic perspective, the more steel-producing (and steel-consuming) countries that join, the more market advantage that would be provided for lower-carbon steel and aluminum. However, negotiating the mechanics of a carbon-based trade regime with so many countries may force negotiators to lower their ambition to meet the needs of the “lowest common denominator.” Balancing ambition—and certainly, high standards for industrial decarbonization, labor rights, and dealing with overcapacity—with the desire for inclusivity will thus be critically important.

It will also be essential to consider when and how new partner countries could join. Ideally, the arrangement would be open to anyone willing to adopt the common tariff scheme and able to meet the prerequisite standards, but participants may want to impose additional requirements, such as the approval of the existing participants—a common requirement in trade agreements. Relatedly, negotiators must also consider how and when to enforce the terms of the arrangement against existing partner countries. Environmental treaties such as the Montreal Protocol contain compliance mechanisms that could provide a model, and participants may wish to consider even harsher sanctions, such as possible expulsion from the global arrangement for participants who persistently fail to meet their obligations.

What should the tariff structure be?

Negotiators should consider setting three tariff rates in order to balance simplicity and functionality with climate impact:

  1. A tariff rate for steel and aluminum that is produced in a market that is part of the global arrangement and with a carbon intensity below a specific limit
  2. A higher tariff rate for steel and aluminum produced in a market that is part of the global arrangement but with a carbon intensity that is above the limit
  3. An even higher tariff rate that would presumptively apply to steel and aluminum produced in a country outside the global arrangement, regardless of its carbon intensity, unless nonparticipants could demonstrate that they have complied with the arrangement’s standards

For example, steel and aluminum imports that meet the conditions under the first rate could be tariffed at 0  percent. Steel and aluminum imports that meet the conditions under the second rate could be tariffed at 25 percent. And steel and aluminum imports that meet neither the first nor second rates could be tariffed at 75 percent, or even face an outright ban, unless the importer can verify that it meets some or all of the arrangement’s standards. A nonparticipant exporter could potentially be entitled to a tariff rate lower than that ordinarily charged under the third rate if the metal falls below a specific carbon-intensity threshold and the exporter can demonstrate full compliance with all the arrangement’s standards, including labor standards and treatment of imports from nonmarket economies.

Such a structure would ensure that joining the global arrangement—with its commitments related to labor rights, broad decarbonization, treatment of imports from nonmarket economies, and R&D cooperation—provides a country with advantages that could not be obtained simply by producing low-carbon steel without ensuring labor rights or addressing overcapacity. Dramatically simplifying the tariff structure within GASSA could also expand the domestic toolkit to ensure the industry does, in fact, decarbonize.

One alternative structure could have the tariff rate slide based on the carbon intensity of the product—essentially a common CBAM. Rather than have two different tariff rates, one for low-carbon steel and aluminum and another for high-carbon steel and aluminum, the structure would assign a tariff rate based on a set conversion factor relative to the amount of carbon in the piece of steel or aluminum. This would more easily align the carbon-based tariff to other carbon border adjustments but would likely run into implementation, transparency, and predictability issues. In addition, unless steel produced with less than a specific level of carbon were allowed to enter another partner’s market tariff-free, it would ensure that at least some tariff was assigned to every imported product, reducing the potential attractiveness of significantly investing in decarbonization—and likely limiting the attractiveness of joining the global arrangement for some potential participants. Indeed, the amount of paperwork involved with tracking and verifying precise carbon intensities, as well as trying to account for the interaction with nonparticipants’ CBAMs, is itself a substantial barrier to trade in green steel and aluminum—a criticism of the EU CBAM and a feature that could significantly weaken the incentives to invest in and trade green metals.

Another alternative would be to have a single tariff rate for participants of the global arrangement—likely zero—and a much higher rate for nonparticipants. This would maximize simplicity and could provide a further incentive for markets to join the arrangement. However, this approach might also offer too great an advantage for the dirtiest steel producers in markets that join the arrangement: They would be granted the same market advantage as less carbon-intensive producers in their same market. This problem could be solved by requiring each participant to adopt similar domestic carbon intensity standards for steel and aluminum production. But a benefit of the GASSA-like structure is that it allows participants some flexibility in how they approach domestic regulation of carbon. This is a significant difference from, and improvement over, the EU CBAM, which exempts only countries that adopt a domestic carbon pricing scheme linked to the European Union’s Emissions Trading System.

What separates high-carbon steel and aluminum?

Assuming a multitier tariff design outlined above, negotiators must choose the line that would separate the low and high tariff rates for steel and aluminum imported from other participants of the global arrangement—that is, the line between the first and second tariff rates detailed above. Several options exist, including a demarcation line based on the importing country’s average emissions in its steel and/or aluminum sector. This approach would ensure that the more a country’s steel and aluminum sector decarbonizes, the more trade protection it would receive. The challenge, however, is that such a system would be difficult to predict going forward, as the national average would change frequently, albeit hopefully always in a cleaner direction. This could slow investment and hamper the types of long-term procurement contracts common in the industry. It would also give the dirtiest steel producers in a market an advantage since they would benefit from the decarbonization investments of their competitors.

A second option would be to set the demarcation line based on the exporting markets’ carbon intensity, ensuring that only those companies that produce low-carbon steel relative to their domestic competitors would have access to the markets of other global arrangement participants. This may incentivize investment in multiple places simultaneously. The challenge, though, with this option is that a market with a higher-than-normal average carbon intensity could have its steel and aluminum advantaged in the market instead of lower-carbon steel produced in a fellow global arrangement participant where the national average is lower. Another concern is that this option could encourage creative resource shuffling without an overall decline in carbon intensity. Both options also involve participants having different demarcation lines, further complicating trade among participants and reducing the value of joining.

For this reason, a third option may be preferable: setting the demarcation line based purely on a particular carbon-intensity score. The benefit of this approach is that it provides long-term transparency; investors know that if they can produce steel and aluminum at a certain level, they will receive the market advantage that comes from being able to export duty-free into other global arrangement markets. It would also allow negotiators to set a carbon intensity demarcation line that decreases over time, driving continual investment in decarbonization, while dealing with issues of resource shuffling through the prerequisite commitments that partners would make to join the arrangement. While this could incentivize the carbon intensity of individual firms’ production to bunch at or near the demarcation line, the peg to a specific carbon score would ensure that the entire sector’s decarbonization efforts would at least be sufficient to achieve broader climate objectives. The line could be set to achieve the carbon emissions levels needed to meet a particular climate target—for example, 1.5 degrees Celsius. If negotiators ultimately choose this option, determining the appropriate carbon level and rate of decline will be extremely important, and likely quite contentious.

Moreover, negotiators should consider the practicality and expediency of developing different demarcation lines for steel produced from electric arc furnaces and blast furnaces. This bifurcation would create incentives to reduce emissions in blast furnace steel production—which will remain a significant component of American and global steel production for the foreseeable future—and avoid a scenario where GASSA creates a protected market for electric arc furnace-produced steel with little incentive for further decarbonization. By giving blast furnaces an incentive to decarbonize even if they cannot meet the same decarbonization standards as electric arc furnaces, this bifurcation would address the resource-shuffling problem in which blast furnace production is consumed domestically and not decarbonized. This sort of bifurcation is already happening at the federal level through the Biden administration’s new Buy Clean policy and is under consideration in Europe through the European Union’s CBAM. Notably, steel produced in the United States is far less carbon intensive than steel produced in China, regardless of the method used to make the steel. Chinese steel produced by the traditional blast furnace produces about 50 percent more emissions than steel made by a blast furnace in the United States. In contrast, steel produced by an electric arc furnace in China is roughly three times more carbon intensive than steel produced by similar processes in the United States.

Is there a limit on the amount of tariff-free steel and aluminum allowed to enter a market?

The current import regime negotiated by the United States with the European Union, Japan, the United Kingdom, and others allows for a tariff rate quota, above which imported steel is tariffed at 25 percent. A global arrangement structure could potentially cap the amount of low-carbon steel allowed to enter a domestic market tariff-free, creating a fourth tariff level for low-carbon steel exceeding a set amount. This fourth tariff rate would likely be below the tariff on high-carbon steel from global arrangement participants but still be assessed some level of tariff since it would exceed the cap allowed to be imported tariff-free. However, to promote design simplicity and provide a strong incentive to decarbonize, the authors support removing any import limit for low-carbon steel produced by a global arrangement partner.

How is carbon intensity measured?

Negotiators must decide whether the carbon-intensity score assigned to a piece of steel or aluminum includes Scope I, Scope II, and/or Scope III emissions. From a climate perspective, including all three makes the most sense. However, this raises considerable transparency, reporting, and verification challenges. Scope I emissions are the easiest to assess and will likely become required because of regulatory actions in most places. Scope II emissions are more challenging and likely not something that every steel and aluminum producer can accurately calculate at present, but they also account for a lot of the carbon advantage U.S. steel producers enjoy over others. And Scope III emissions may be even harder to calculate for most firms—and even harder to verify for everyone else. But without a process to estimate Scope III emissions, the threat of the global arrangement failing to accurately account for major sources of emissions is simply too high.

 

Scope I, II, and III emissions in the steel and aluminum sectors

Understanding the different types of emissions is important to assessing the carbon intensity of a particular product. In the steel and aluminum sectors, Scope I emissions refer to direct emissions produced in the production of a metal. This can be the result of running machines (blast furnaces, for example) as well as the electricity used to power facilities used in production. Scope II emissions are created by the production of energy that is purchased by a steel and aluminum manufacturer in its production. And Scope III emissions refer to those caused by a steel and aluminum company’s suppliers and customers, as well as the emissions caused in transporting component parts and materials to a production facility.

 

For this reason, the United States and the European Union—and others, if the global arrangement negotiations are expanded—should name a team of technical experts to develop a consistent, uniform, and mutually acceptable methodology for calculating the embedded emissions of a piece of steel or aluminum, as well as plans to educate steel producers and consumers on how to use the methodology. This will likely include using environmental product declarations or other commonly used reporting mechanisms.

One thing to note: It may be possible to evolve this part of the global arrangement over time if, for example, in the first years of the system, only Scope I emissions could be included. Eventually, the system could expand to include Scope II and Scope III emissions, perhaps providing global arrangement participants the opportunity to develop a consistent, transparent, and verifiable method for calculating the impact of these emissions on a product’s unique carbon-intensity score.

At what level is a steel or aluminum product assessed a carbon-intensity score?

Today, when a product shows up at a border, it is assessed a tariff based on its harmonized tariff schedule (HTS) code and its country of origin. HTS codes are harmonized globally at the six-digit level, meaning trade can flow relatively easily. But such a system of harmonized codes does not work for carbon intensity, so negotiators must agree on how to score a piece of steel or aluminum. In a perfect world, each piece of steel or aluminum would be assigned its own unique score, but this is challenging given the limitations of existing data. Nevertheless, working toward common standards for this type of product-specific carbon accounting should remain a goal for any government that wishes to join GASSA or a GASSA-like agreement.

An alternative might be to assign a piece of steel or aluminum a carbon score based solely on the market in which it was produced—essentially a national average. This would mean that a piece of steel produced in Canada would be assigned the Canadian carbon score. Canadian industry as a whole would have an incentive then to lower its overall emissions profile. Still, laggard firms would benefit the most from the decarbonization investments of their domestic competitors. This free-rider problem alone likely makes this approach unworkable in the absence of common domestic standards on decarbonization. Moreover, a national average would need to be regularly—likely annually—assessed and agreed to by other participants of the global arrangement. In addition to the free-rider problem, this approach could cause incessant bickering among global arrangement participants, as minor changes to a country’s national average could have important ramifications in the business environment—and, of course, each country’s government would strongly support its own domestic industry.

Another option would be to assess a carbon score based on the carbon emissions of the factory that created the piece of steel or aluminum. This would align better to the inclusion of Scope I, Scope II, and Scope III emissions, as Scope II and III emissions are often plant-specific, and would ensure that each company would benefit from its investments in decarbonization. However, if a plant significantly improved its carbon footprint, it might not enjoy the market advantage such an investment would entail until the next update to the plant’s carbon score. For instance, if plants were assigned a carbon score annually, an investment that is completed in January would wait another 11 months before it would be reflected in the import price of that company’s products.

 

Research underway into the emissions intensity of steel and aluminum production

The Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) already runs a Greenhouse Gas Reporting Program that collects and publishes emissions data from the metals sector, including steel and aluminum. The International Trade Commission (ITC) is currently investigating the greenhouse gas emissions intensity of steel and aluminum production in the United States, collecting both company- and facility-specific data. The results of the ITC investigation will supplement the data the EPA already collects to give the U.S. government an overall picture of the relationship between emissions in the steel and aluminum sectors and international trade flows.

 

 

When would the global arrangement take effect?

From a climate perspective, the faster a global arrangement system starts, the better. But it might be relevant to garner support for the arrangement to delay implementation to allow for decarbonization investments to come online.

Are there exclusions for products not made domestically?

Another decision point revolves around whether steel and aluminum products that are unavailable domestically should be subject to an exclusions process that would allow them to be imported duty-free into the market of a global arrangement member. From a climate perspective, this would create a significant loophole that could decrease the carbon impact of the global arrangement. But from a market, competitiveness, and political perspective, it may be necessary to continue offering tariff exclusions for those products not currently available in a country’s home market. If exclusions are offered, negotiators will need to determine whether the imported steel or aluminum must be from another global arrangement partner or from anyone. The preference would be the former, but it is possible that the product may not be available from any other global arrangement participant either, particularly if the arrangement is limited to only a few markets.

While not a large source of imported steel, negotiators may also consider providing some level of tariff-free exclusion for green steel produced in markets classified as a least developed country (LDC). Such an exclusion would be subject to a quantitative limit above which the standard GASSA tariffs would apply to avoid LDCs becoming pass-through jurisdictions for exporters from countries outside the arrangement seeking preferential access to GASSA markets. This could encourage broader investment in green steel production outside traditional markets, offering a pathway for LDCs to help shape the future of the steel industry more sustainably.

Is all steel and aluminum included?

The current HTS system includes 58 steel product categories, and the United States maintains roughly 800 10-digit import codes in the sector. Negotiators will need to determine whether the global arrangement should include all these unique products, or only imports in certain categories. Moreover, negotiators will need to consider whether downstream steel and aluminum products should be subject to similar carbon-based tariffs. Including all steel and aluminum products would be the most impactful from a climate perspective and would eliminate the need to negotiate along individual tariff lines or to parse finished goods into their component parts or materials, but it may make implementation unwieldy.

What is more, given the intricacies of different metals supply chains, it is important that GASSA participants agree that the preferential tariffs that apply to GASSA participants only apply to products melted and poured (in the case of steel) or smelted and cast (in the case of aluminum) in another GASSA participant’s territory. This would ensure that steel and aluminum produced in a nonmarket economy are not offered a backdoor to the advantageous terms offered by GASSA membership.

How can carbon-intensity scores be verified?

It is critical to the functioning of any economic system that the participants trust the information they receive from others. Suppose a steel or aluminum producer is selling to a buyer in another global arrangement market. In that case, the two sides must trust that the carbon score reported by the producer is valid, and thus their product will be assessed an import tariff at the appropriate rate. However, this variable—unlike the product’s HTS code and country of origin—is subject to change. Thus, a question arises about when the score changes and who verifies that it is correct. Is there an independent verifier, or will the participants themselves do the verification? Participants will also want to negotiate penalties for false, and possibly for mistaken, reporting.

How should revenue raised from carbon tariffs be used?

Currently, revenue generated by tariffs is deposited into the U.S. Treasury. However, revenue generated from GASSA or a GASSA-like structure does not necessarily need to be treated the same way, although this would likely require a legislative change. It could, for example, be invested in certain activities such as additional industrial decarbonization projects, R&D, and more. The tariff could be structured to use the revenue generated to supercharge industrial decarbonization efforts and to better prepare steel and aluminum producers within participants of the global arrangement to address competition from nonmarket practices elsewhere. Another option would be to use some of the revenue as foreign aid to countries that are primarily consumers of steel produced elsewhere but lacking an export interest. This could induce these countries to join the global arrangement and/or impose external barriers on dirty steel or aluminum imports. Expanding the global arrangement in this way would provide additional market opportunities for cleaner steel produced in the markets of global arrangement participants while also narrowing the range of markets importing dirty metals, helping to reduce the global price suppression that Chinese overcapacity has inflicted on the global steel and aluminum market.

What is the interaction between GASSA and the EU CBAM?

If the European Union is included in GASSA, negotiators must determine the interaction between GASSA and the EU CBAM. The EU CBAM is essentially a tariff based on carbon intensity on core industrial products, including steel and aluminum. It is a unilateral measure that exempts other countries only insofar as they adopt and link a domestic carbon pricing scheme to the European Union’s system. In this sense, the EU CBAM reflects an effort to get the rest of the world to adopt the European Union’s domestic decarbonization policies. Initial implementation has already begun, and the European Union is set to start collecting import fees in 2026.

If the European Union agreed to join and implement GASSA or GASSA-like structure, negotiators would need to work out whether that structure would replace the CBAM for steel and aluminum imports or be layered on top of it. If the latter, the European Union would need to ensure that low-carbon imports from the United States are not “double-tariffed” under GASSA and the CBAM and that U.S.-produced low-carbon steel and aluminum, and potentially metals produced by other GASSA partners, remain competitive in the EU domestic market relative to dirtier alternatives from within the European Union.

Simply put, failure to adequately address the interaction with the EU CBAM in a manner fair to U.S. steel and aluminum producers, and their workers, would call into question the viability of the European Union as a negotiating partner in developing a GASSA structure. At the same time, the European Union—long a leader in tackling climate change—has invested much political capital in building its CBAM. The European Union may hope that by 2025 or 2026, political and regulatory momentum—both in the European Union and in other countries eager to minimize the burden on their exports to the European Union—will make the CBAM and the associated domestic carbon pricing schemes the de facto global standard. For this reason, the United States should move quickly in discussions with other allies if the European Union continues to prove reluctant.

 

Design for maximum effect

Negotiators in the United States and like-minded countries should seize the opportunity to create a new precedent for climate-friendly trade cooperation. And more important than demonstrating conviction is getting these design choices right. Negotiators should assess how different policy choices will affect key outcomes. These outcomes include:

  • Overall carbon emissions of the steel and aluminum sector within global arrangement markets
  • Overall emissions of the steel and aluminum sector globally
  • Trade flows, since the changes in tariff rates would result in a changing of how steel and aluminum is imported and exported around the world
  • Steel production, including where production takes place and how it is produced—for example, blast furnaces or electric arc
  • Job creation and, to the extent possible, job creation by factory, state, and market

Understanding and messaging the impact of the policy choices that can improve these outcomes will be essential to maximizing the value of the carbon-based trade arrangement and to building the political support needed to ensure the arrangement endures into the future.

 

Conclusion

Rarely in international economic policy is an opportunity so clearly a win for the climate, workers, and foreign policy. Although the decision points are novel, they represent the cutting edge of trade policy. Put simply, GASSA portends a new way of thinking about global trade, one that more closely resembles the values of trading partners rather than simple efficiency at the expense of workers or the environment. It is a chance to set a crucial new precedent that the Biden administration and U.S. allies should seize.

 

To read the full report as it is published on the Center for American Progress’ website, click here.

The post Designing a New Paradigm in Global Trade appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Ain’t No Duty High Enough /atp-research/no-duty-enough/ Tue, 30 Apr 2024 02:40:29 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=45167 The European Commission is likely to impose countervailing duties on imports of electric vehicles (EV) from China in the coming months to head off the risk of subsidized cars damaging...

The post Ain’t No Duty High Enough appeared first on WITA.

]]>
The European Commission is likely to impose countervailing duties on imports of electric vehicles (EV) from China in the coming months to head off the risk of subsidized cars damaging Europe’s auto industry. We expect the Commission to impose duties in the 15-30% range. But even if the duties come in at the higher end of this range, some China-based producers will still be able to generate comfortable profit margins on the cars they export to Europe because of the substantial cost advantages they enjoy. Duties in the 40-50% range—arguably even higher for vertically integrated manufacturers like BYD—would probably be necessary to make the European market unattractive for Chinese EV exporters. As countervailing duties at this level are unlikely, policymakers in Brussels may decide to turn to non-traditional tools to shield the European auto industry, including restrictions based on environmental or national security-related factors.

The EU’s anti-subsidy probe

In the biggest EU trade case against China ever, the Commission initiated an anti-subsidy investigation into EV imports from China in October 2023. Should it determine that China-based producers have benefited from subsidies in ways that harm EU-based manufacturers, it could place provisional countervailing duties on China-origin EV imports anytime from now until July 3, and final duties by early November. In March 2024, the Commission asked European customs authorities to track imports of EVs from China, a signal that it could impose provisional duties in the near future.

The EV probe stands out for several reasons. First, the Commission initiated the investigation ex officio, without a formal complaint from industry, which is a rarity in such cases. Second, there is a divide within Europe’s car industry—which accounts for 7% of the EU’s GDP and 8.5% of its manufacturing employment—on the desirability of the probe. German carmakers, which are heavily reliant on the Chinese market, oppose it out of fear that Beijing could retaliate against them, while French counterparts, which are far less exposed to China, support it. Third, the probe is based on the threat that cheap EV imports from China could cause damage to European manufacturers in the future, rather than an assessment that this damage is already taking place. Finally, the probe is perhaps the most political case of its kind in recent memory. Commission President Ursula von der Leyen chose to announce it in her annual state of the union speech last September. And the Commission has focused its investigation on three China-based carmakers—BYD, Geely, and SAIC—rather than western carmakers like Tesla, which exports more EVs from China to the EU than any other producer.

EU imports of EVs from China ballooned from $1.6 billion in 2020 to $11.5 billion in 2023, accounting for 37% of all EV imports in the bloc. While the market share of China-produced EV models in the European market has only increased slightly to 19%, the share of Chinese and Chinese-owned brands has increased substantially in the last two years. This suggests that Chinese companies are gaining momentum in the European market. BYD has said that it is aiming to secure a 5% share of EV sales in Europe by 2026 and to be among the top five automotive companies in Europe in the medium term.

Based on an analysis of previous instances of countervailing duties (CVDs) imposed by the EU on Chinese imports and on conversations with experts, we expect the Commission to consider duties on Chinese EVs in the 15-30% range. This is based on the following factors:

  • The average of the highest duty level imposed in previous anti-subsidy cases against China stands at 24.4%. In rare instances, CVDs have been as high as 40-50%, however these were concentrated on industries with a high degree of direct state-ownership, such as steel, and focused on non-cooperating Chinese entities. In contrast, the EV sector is primarily privately owned in China.
  • The three companies (BYD, Geely, and SAIC) that the Commission has chosen to focus on in its investigation have signaled their willingness to cooperate. This means that they are providing information to the Commission. For non-cooperating firms the Commission estimates duties based on public information, which in the past has resulted in higher duties.

The Commission will calculate individual duties for BYD, Geely, and SAIC, while other exporters such as Tesla will receive a duty based on the weighted average of the duties imposed on the Chinese brands that the Commission deems to have cooperated. Theoretically, the Commission could also opt to impose other remedies, for instance a minimum import price or fixed price, but given the highly complex nature of modern EVs, this is an unlikely and unpractical prospect.

Price analysis of China-based exporters

Currently, the electric vehicle markets in Europe and China are characterized by major price discrepancies which have encouraged producers to export their cars from China to Europe. Intense competition in a saturated Chinese market has led to a price war there and forced manufacturers to boost efficiencies in the pursuit of ever-lower production costs. Volkswagen’s ID.4 model, for example, sells for nearly 50% more in Europe than it does in China. For Chinese producers like BYD, the price gulf is even larger, as they try to compensate for the profit squeeze in China by charging higher prices for their products in the EU. But with exports picking up, some of these price differences are likely to erode over time. Increasingly, Chinese and foreign manufacturers are taking advantage of China’s cheaper labor and energy prices, its more developed battery ecosystem and government subsidies to produce in China for the European and third markets.

Should the EU impose countervailing duties on Chinese EV imports, it would seriously affect incentives for China-based producers to export to Europe. Our price analysis reveals that exports to the EU by China-based producers are very profitable. BYD makes around €14,300 in profit on each SEAL U model sold in the EU, compared to €1,300 on units sold in China. This means that BYD earns €13,000 more on every Seal U model sold in the EU (the “EU premium”). Our analysis is based on the suggested retail prices (MSRPs) of the various manufacturers in China and Germany, and calculates profits after shipping, tariffs, distribution and VAT.

It should be noted that BYD’s relatively low sales numbers in Europe suggest that the prices it is charging in the European market may be too high, especially in light of the fact that it is still a relatively unknown brand. With such a high EU premium, however, the company has ample space to adjust pricing.

In order to substantially reduce the incentive for BYD to export models like the SEAL U to the EU, duties would need to be set at a level that erases the €13,000 premium that the company currently enjoys in Europe. This would bring profit margins in the EU in line with those that BYD enjoys in China. In reality, this is not the goal of the anti-subsidy investigation. It is not meant to render EVs produced in China and sold on the EU market unprofitable, but rather determine whether China’s export competitiveness is based on subsidies. Even if duties were set at a high enough level to erase the EU premium, BYD might decide that exporting to Europe makes sense, given slowing demand and competitive pressures in the Chinese market. One cannot dismiss the possibility that Chinese EV producers would be willing to forgo profits in the short-term and sell at a loss in order to gain market share in the world’s second biggest EV market.

A 30% duty imposed on BYD for the Seal U would fall far short of leveling the playing field between the EU and China as far as the company’s profits on the car are concerned. According to our calculations, a 30% duty would still leave the company with a 15% (€4,700) EU premium in relation to its China profits, meaning that exports to Europe would remain highly attractive. Moreover, duties at this level would provide BYD with space to lower its prices in order to gain market share in Europe. Our analysis of several other models sold in China and Germany indicates that even after a 30% duty, many Chinese EV models would still enjoy a strong EU profit premium.

In short, much steeper duties of around 45%, or even 55% for fiercely competitive producers like BYD, would probably be necessary in order to render exports to the European market unappealing on commercial grounds.

Duties at the 15-30% level could, however, wipe out the business model for foreign players like BMW or Tesla, which are using China as a base for exporting to Europe. For BMW’s iX3 SUV, for example, the EU premium (after accounting for related costs such as shipping) is only 9%, meaning that if duties are above 9%, the company would make less money on sales in Europe than in China. This also means that duties set at the higher end of our range could undermine plans by companies such as BMW, Honda and Volkswagen to expand the use of China as an export hub for the EU market going forward.

The price gap between foreign and Chinese producers is likely due to two main factors: Chinese producers receive more subsidies than foreign producers, although both benefit from Chinese government support, and Chinese companies are more vertically integrated and can procure products at lower prices than their foreign competitors.

Chinese producers will likely need to export

While duties would make exporting to the EU less attractive, several factors suggest that China’s EV export push will continue to gain momentum in the coming years:

Slowing growth and tighter profit margins at home: While China’s new energy vehicle (NEV) market has expanded rapidly, with sales surging by 97% in 2022 and 38% in 2023, growth is expected to decelerate significantly due to the higher base and China’s economic slowdown. Cui Dongshu, the Secretary General of China’s passenger vehicle association, forecasts that NEV sales growth will drop to 22% in 2024. Moreover, intense competition has led to a price war, resulting in profit margins in the auto sector plummeting from 8.7% in 2015 to 4.3% in 2023. Both of these trends are making exports much more appealing to China-based producers.

New production capacity coming online: Bolstered by robust profits and government backing, Chinese EV manufacturers have made substantial investments in new production facilities. This additional capacity will hit the market soon. BYD’s new plants illustrate this: By 2026, BYD’s production capacity in China will reach 6.55 million EVs up from 2.9 million at the end of 2023. To fully utilize all this capacity BYD would need to more than double its domestic EV sales—a challenging feat given the anticipated slowdown in China’s overall EV sales. Even to maintain capacity utilization at 80%, BYD would need to increase domestic sales by 81% by 2026.

New shipping capacity coming online: China’s EV exports have been hindered by a scarcity of affordable car shipping vessels. In 2023, charter prices for such carriers skyrocketed by 700% compared to 2019, exacerbated by Houthi attacks in the Red Sea, further straining shipping capacity and inflating costs. However, Chinese carmakers and shipping companies have responded by placing orders for numerous new ships. Based on these orders, they will have capacity to ship an estimated 560,000 cars annually to Europe in 2025, based on six trips a year (in 2023 the EU imported 472,000 EVs from China). Capacity could surge to as much as 1.7 million cars in 2026. In the unlikely case that all ships were used for transporting cars to Europe, the volumes exported from China would likely be enough to capture 50% of the EU’s EV market. Notably, the decision to purchase rather than rent car-carrying ships underscores the long-term goal of Chinese EV producers to export large quantities of cars.

Lack of other attractive export markets: The EU, the world’s second biggest EV market, is likely to remain the primary destination for China-made EVs. With its plans for a de facto ban on internal combustion engine (ICE) vehicles from 2035, and various support mechanisms in place, the EU presents a highly attractive market—especially compared to the US, which already has high tariffs on Chinese EVs in place and is planning further measures to restrict Chinese carmakers. Exports to other markets will be challenging for other reasons: either they are smaller, lag behind in EV adoption or will be served by local production, often because of local content requirements (ASEAN, Brazil, India and Mexico).

Ambitious targets for the European market: BYD has set an ambitious goal to capture a 5% market share in Europe even before its Hungary plant commences operations in 2026. This would entail selling approximately 130,000 EVs in Europe in 2025, a massive increase from the 16,000 sold in 2023. Looking ahead to 2030, the company aims to account for 10% of Europe’s EV market, corresponding to an estimated 920,000 vehicles, with a portion produced in its Hungary plant and the majority likely imported from China. These targets are consistent with those communicated by Shenzhen’s municipal government, where BYD is headquartered. The city wants to increase NEV exports from 71,000 in 2023 (January to November) to 400,000 in 2024 and to 600,000 in 2025. It released a 24-point plan to achieve these goals in November 2023. Similarly, SAIC-owned MG, having sold nearly 232,000 vehicles in Europe last year, plans to sell more than 300,000 cars this year.

EU officials might consider additional tools

If duties fail to slow Chinese exporters, at a time when China continues to incentivize firms to export, the Commission may feel the need to explore alternative measures. Competition Commissioner Margrethe Vestager floated this idea in a speech at Princeton University in April, calling for the introduction of “trustworthiness” criteria at G7 level based on factors like environmental footprint, labor rights, cybersecurity, and data security. A range of options are on the table:

Cybersecurity: The EU could attempt to tighten cybersecurity requirements to restrict market access for Chinese EV producers. Similar to the 5G Toolbox it published in January 2020, the EU could establish policy guidelines for member states that designate Chinese EVs as a cybersecurity risk due to the integration of cameras and sensors in cars and Beijing’s close oversight of China-based producers. Although most EVs will be privately purchased, member states could also decide to include “trustworthiness” criteria in public tender documents.

This approach would, however, face numerous obstacles, as the uneven implementation of the 5G Toolbox illustrates. National security remains primarily a member state prerogative, and convincing all members that Chinese EVs pose a national security risk will be challenging, particularly as some fear retaliation against their own products in China. A fragmented solution that restricts Chinese EVs in some countries but not others, would be problematic given the Schengen Zone’s open borders. Unlike 5G, where the costs to replace untrusted equipment would be shouldered by telecommunications operators, cybersecurity-related restrictions on connected vehicles would directly affect consumers.

Moreover, the notion that cybersecurity measures would serve as a panacea is tempered by the availability of Chinese smartphones in the EU, which arguably pose a greater risk but enjoy substantial market share with Xiaomi and Huawei ranking as the third and fourth biggest smartphone brands in 2023. While some member states, such as Belgium and Lithuania, have expressed cybersecurity-related concerns about Chinese phones, others disagree. With the automotive industry, the economic stakes are considerably higher.

Conditioning EV purchasing subsidies: Many European member states offer purchasing incentives to spur the adoption of electric vehicles. Member states could follow the lead of France and tweak regulations to restrict Chinese-made EVs based on sustainability criteria. This would place Chinese EVs at a severe competitive disadvantage. However, member states would have to act fast as most subsidy schemes are already on their way to being phased out. Additionally, if countries use environmental standards to penalize Chinese exporters as France is doing, Chinese companies could limit the damage by decarbonizing their production.

Forced labor regulation: A new EU measure banning products made with forced labor could be used to restrict the import of Made in China EVs. A recent report by Human Rights Watch found that many big OEMs including BYD, Tesla and Volkswagen could be procuring aluminum produced with forced labor. US authorities recently impounded cars produced by Volkswagen Group over allegations that they violated the Uyghur Forced Labor Prevention Act. The long lead time that is foreseen for implementation of the EU’s forced labor ban illustrates the limits of using this tool as a near- or medium-term solution for restricting imports.

Reviewing subsidies in procurement and investments: The EU’s new foreign subsidy regulation facilitates the review of large procurement contracts exceeding €250 million. However, it’s unlikely that many EV contracts will surpass this threshold. For instance, BYD secured a contract in December to supply 640 EVs for Austria’s federal government, likely for around €20 million considering MSRPs. Still, the use of EU funds, like REPowerEU, to support BYD in Hungary has prompted concerns that could lead to policy adjustments going forward.

Scaling back Europe’s EV ambitions: In 2022, the EU effectively instituted an internal combustion engine ban by implementing progressively stricter fleet emission targets, compelling manufacturers to elevate the proportion of EVs or incur penalties. Nonetheless, confronted with the considerable expenses associated with the EV transition and the surge in Chinese competition, certain segments of the European automotive industry and conservative parties across Europe have voiced opposition to the target. A review of the 2035 target, slated for 2026, presents an opportunity to recalibrate objectives, potentially buying ICE-focused European incumbents time and curbing the competitiveness of Chinese EV producers.

A more drastic review of WTO rules: In her Princeton speech in April 2024, Vestager voiced the view that the EU needs a more comprehensive approach to tackling Chinese distortions. One such way would be to raise tariffs on China across the board. This is highly unlikely for now, but could gain momentum if the US moves first. The Select Committee on China in the House of Representatives has called for the removal of Permanent Normal Trade Relations status for China, which would increase tariffs for Chinese goods across the board.

What to watch

We expect the Commission to place provisional duties on Chinese EV imports by early July. Going ahead we are also watching for:

Member state pushback: Before the imposition of final duties (by early November 2024) EU member states could try to block the EU’s case in the Trade Defence Instruments Committee. This would require a qualified majority of member states to vote against duties, something that has never been achieved before in an EU anti-subsidy investigation. German politicians and carmakers have signaled that they do not support the case. France, on the other hand, has made clear that it sees the need for EU action. Whether Berlin would risk a fight over the EV case is unclear. But we have seen Germany’s divided coalition government stand in the way of EU measures that were well advanced in recent months, notably refusing to support sustainability due diligence legislation.

Chinese retaliation: In January 2024, China launched an anti-dumping probe into brandy imports from the EU. The move was widely seen as a retaliatory move aimed at France, which was a vocal supporter of the EU’s trade case against Chinese EV imports. Should the EU impose duties, China is likely to do the same on brandy imports. It could also take other steps, for example responding in kind against EU automakers, tightening the regulatory screws on other European companies with a presence in China, or restricting the supply of critical minerals to Europe’s fledgling battery sector. Beijing, which is keen to avoid a tit-for-tat trade conflict with Europe that could further impeded its access to the European market, may wait until final duties are imposed before responding.

Following up with an anti-dumping probe: The EU chose to launch an anti-subsidy investigation into EVs rather than opt for an anti-dumping probe, which would have allowed it to impose higher tariffs. The decision to go down this path was likely driven by the fact that anti-dumping cases have a higher burden of proof and because Chinese producers have not priced their products extremely cheaply in Europe. Should Chinese EV exporters absorb the countervailing duties and subsequently lower their prices to gain market share in the EU, the Commission could follow up with an anti-dumping case at some point in the future.

Chinese EV sales figures in Europe: In recent months, Chinese EV exports to the EU have declined against a backdrop of high shipping costs, policy uncertainty, and major changes to EV purchasing subsidies in France and Germany. A continued decline in Chinese EV sales could reduce the political momentum for additional policy measures beyond the EV duties that are expected before the summer. A renewed surge of Chinese EV exports, by contrast, would increase the likelihood that new tools, including the measures floated by Vestager in her April speech, would be considered.

Chinese EV investment: In contrast to the US, the EU has remained open to Chinese investments in the EV sector. In December 2023, BYD announced plans to build a factory in Hungary. In April 2024, Chery signed a JV deal with Spanish EV Motors to produce cars in Catalonia. Were more Chinese brands to announce plans to invest in local production facilities in Europe, this could alleviate pressures in the bilateral trade relationship. It is also possible, however, that Chinese brands could come under scrutiny if they are producing cars that undercut European rivals. This could trigger cases under the EU’s Foreign Subsidies Regulation. Chinese brands could also face a backlash within Europe if their production facilities remain concentrated in China-friendly countries like Hungary, the country that has attracted the majority of EV-related investments by Chinese firms so far.

Aint-No-Duty-High-Enough

To read the full report as published by the Rhodium Group, click here.

To read the full report, click here.

The post Ain’t No Duty High Enough appeared first on WITA.

]]>
US Sets Trade Policy Sights on China’s Xinjiang /atp-research/us-chinas-xinjiang/ Tue, 19 Mar 2024 20:33:35 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=43029 As Washington escalates its raft of trade controls against China, the US Uyghur Forced Labor Prevention Act is likely to be a key piece of legislation impelling the momentum. Now...

The post US Sets Trade Policy Sights on China’s Xinjiang appeared first on WITA.

]]>
As Washington escalates its raft of trade controls against China, the US Uyghur Forced Labor Prevention Act is likely to be a key piece of legislation impelling the momentum. Now more than ever, multinationals may have to be more artful in engineering the separation of their Chinese and non-Chinese business operations – and the origins of their parts.

The US is mulling an end to the de minimis provision that allows shipments valued under US$800 to enter the world’s largest consumer market, a move largely aimed at Chinese exports. Such a move would escalate a raft of trade controls Washington has already placed against China, including controls on semiconductor technology and outbound investment.

In many ways, a key piece of legislation impelling the momentum is the US Uyghur Forced Labor Prevention Act (UFLPA). Passed in late 2021, the ambition of the UFLPA is far more comprehensive than the “small yard, high fence” scope of containment policies, as it seeks to restrict imports in toto from an entire region inextricably linked to global supply chains. Growing political pressure and technical know-how within the retooled oversight agencies portend much more robust UFLPA enforcement across a growing category of goods.

This is likely to be one of the more conspicuous developments in the US’ international trade posture in 2024. The Biden administration signaled last week that it may escalate controls on China’s access to sophisticated semiconductor technologies, as Commerce Secretary Gina Raimondo vowed “we will do whatever it takes.” Alongside these tech controls, Washington has existing policy weapons it could use to target the extent to which Xinjiang is embedded in global supply chains, including in strategic industries suffused with Chinese overcapacity. Early signs of enhanced enforcement action suggest a particular focus on the automotive sector.

Washington’s new trade Zeitgeist

The Biden administration has never quite succinctly enunciated its trade doctrine. Reindustrializing the country, de-risking, and an emphasis on labor rights and the environment have been moving parts of a vast policy machine.

A renewed focus on supply chains, which have become ever more complex and specialized as globalization has advanced, is at the core of this otherwise disparate agenda.

The UFPLA is a case in point and epitomizes the complexity and scope of Washington’s new trade agenda. In the words of international trade law expert John Foote, the UFLPA is “the most trade impacting law that was not actually crafted as trade legislation. It was adopted, ultimately as a piece of human rights legislation”.

The core raison d’etre for the UFPLA is the extensive body of evidence suggesting that forced labor is an integral pillar of Beijing’s objective to eradicate or at least Sinicize Uyghur Muslim culture, through coercing Uyghurs into adopting the lifestyles and values of China’s Han majority.

The UFPLA’s sweeping “rebuttable presumption” assumes that, unless proven otherwise (a very high bar given the opacity of Xinjiang), all goods shipped from Xinjiang are made using forced labor by Uyghur or other Muslim minorities. As well as facilitating the seizure of goods at US ports, the UFPLA has instituted an Entity List. The shipments of companies on the Entity List are automatically impounded at US ports irrespective of their geographic origin.

The enormity of the UFPLA’s ambition is difficult to overstate. As a conduit point for the sprawling Belt and Road Initiative’s Eurasian economic corridor, Xinjiang is far from an economic backwater. According to official figures, exports are booming, totaling more than US$45 billion in the first 11 months of 2023.

Xinjiang produces roughly 50% of the world’s polysilicon, 25% of its tomatoes, and 20% of its cotton. The western region is also a sizable producer of textiles, steel, and quartz. Xinjiang now produces about 9% of global aluminum and plays a growing role in automotive supply chains.

As a global workshop for raw materials and metals production, Xinjiang goods invariably pass through several intermediaries straddling multiple borders before ultimately ending up in Western markets. An incredibly granular understanding of global supply chains with dense networks of suppliers and sub-suppliers is required to preclude the possibility of Xinjiang content ending up in finished goods. The challenge for US authorities has been exacerbated by Uyghur work groups being routinely dispatched to work in other parts of China.

A work in progress

After the bill’s passage in December 2021, U.S. Customs and Border Protection (CBP), overseen by the Department of Homeland Security (DHS), had just 180 days to work out how to enforce the UFPLA.

The CBP faced a steep learning curve, possessing little Mandarin language capability or supply chain mapping expertise. The CBP has had to lean heavily on the expertise of academics and non-governmental organizations (NGOs) to keep up.

One group that has been particularly instrumental is the Forced Labour Lab at Britain’s Sheffield Hallam University. The Lab’s methodology (largely focusing on parsing publicly available Chinese company reports and press releases) is explicitly geared toward exposing Western companies’ complicity with Uyghur human rights’ abuses. The DHS hired the consultancy of Laura Murphy, an expert on forced labor practices who has led the Lab’s work since 2019.

Tellingly, almost all the additions to the UFLPA’s Entity List to date which were not already on other sanctions lists, were identified in Sheffield Hallam’s research. One example is automotive supplier Sichuan Jingweida Technology Group, which was named in a 2022 report as having accepted Uyghur laborers transferred from Xinjiang in 2018. Jingweida, which counts China’s SAIC Motor Corp. and EVTech (which in turn supplies Nio, Renault, and Volkswagen) as major customers, was ultimately added to the Entity List in December 2023.

Show me results

Through external research collaboration and the integration of tools like AI-powered supply chain mapping software, the CBP is making up for lost time. As of February, the CBP has detained over 7,000 shipments of goods traced to Xinjiang worth more than US$2.6 billion, with the vast majority of these having arrived Stateside in the last year.

This figure is almost certainly only a drop in the ocean. As was made clear in the July 2023 strategy update by the interagency taskforce overseeing UFLPA enforcement, the CBP now has the means to move beyond the initial high-priority sectors of cotton, tomatoes, and polysilicon to “all sectors identified by NGOs”. This includes copper, aluminum and steel products, lithium-ion batteries, tires, and other automobile components.

The Entity List, which had 20 companies until June 2023, has now grown to 30. The DHS has publicly stated that expanding the list is a priority.

Increased technical capacity and new hires are driving more rigorous enforcement. Another factor is a hefty dosage of political pressure – or indeed cover – provided by an eclectic coalition of NGOs, Uyghur groups abroad, and sympathetic members of Congress.

A late January 2024 letter published by the bipartisan Congressional Select Committee on the Chinese Communist Party – which has been influential in setting the hawkish tenor of congressional discourse – is instructive.

The letter exhorts the DHS to add companies “outside the People’s Republic of China” to the Entity List and “exponentially” increase testing and enforcement action at ports. The former could be a point of tension in US trade relations with Vietnam and Malaysia. Both countries have been the largest point of origin for shipments seized under the UFLPA, as Chinese companies have become more adept at circumventing tariffs and concealing Xinjiang content.

Another focus of the Select Committee’s campaign is changing the rules around de minimis eligibility for high-risk items. Under the de minimis provision, goods valued at less than US$800 are not subject to routine customs checks and duties. The Select Committee has been vociferous in highlighting concerns that e-commerce giants Temu and SHEIN are using de minimis as a loophole to ship textiles containing Xinjiang cotton.

Automotive industry in the crosshairs

There are strong early signs that the CBP’s enhanced capacity and political sentiment on the Hill are galvanizing more aggressive enforcement.

In an unprecedented development that has raised hackles in the Western automotive industry, an undisclosed number of vehicles were detained at US ports in mid-February. The cars, reported to be in the thousands and belonging to Porsche, Bentley, and Audi, allegedly contain a subcomponent produced by a company in western China.

It is understood that the Volkswagen (VW) parent group – which owns these three brands – alerted US authorities after it was made aware of the subcomponent by one of its primary China-based suppliers. The subcomponent in question was ultimately manufactured by one of the VW network’s indirect suppliers far, far down the supply chain.

For VW, this was just one part of a mensis horribilis. VW is now actively reassessing the future of its joint venture (JV) with SAIC in Xinjiang after the German newspaper Handelsblatt published evidence showing that the JV used Uyghur forced labor in the construction of a test track for cars in 2019.

VW’s February pledge to review its JV comes after a highly controversial company audit published in December 2023 appeared to exonerate VW of allegations of forced labor at its Xinjiang factory. On cue, the Select Committee in February wrote to VW Group Chief Executive Officer Oliver Blume urging his company to cease operations in Xinjiang.

VW is now in an acutely invidious position, having bet heavily on the Chinese market (and its partnership with SAIC) as a key plank of its strategy to remain globally competitive against China Inc.’s electric vehicle (EV) juggernaut. Closing its Xinjiang factory, as seems to be the only tenable option at this stage, risks inevitable blowback from Beijing – even if this chagrin is largely performative so regulators can use it to deter other companies.

VW’s issues are only the thin edge of the wedge. As far back as December 2022, a report from the Sheffield Lab suggested that over 50 international automotive companies were “sourcing directly” from Xinjiang or from Chinese companies who have accepted forced labor transfers.

Chinese-owned companies with aggressive battery or EV export ambitions including Contemporary Amperex Technology (CATL), SAIC, Volvo Cars, Nio Inc., and GAC Aion New Energy Automobile Co., were also named as having a material Xinjiang footprint.

The scope of this problem extends right down into the weeds of automotive supply chains. A February 2024 Human Rights Watch (HRW) report raised severe concerns over aluminum procurement practices. The report explicitly names Tesla, Toyota, General Motors, and BYD as being at risk of using Xinjiang-sourced aluminum.

With US officials evincing particular concern that Europe will become a “dumping ground” for goods made in Xinjiang, forced labor could become another point of dispute in the transatlantic trade relationship. In late February, opposition from Germany and Italy scuppered the adoption of the European Union’s own belated forced labor law, the Corporate Sustainability Due Diligence Directive (CSDDD).

Conclusion

The growing preparedness of Washington to enforce existing regulations gels with the current anxiety over China’s automotive expert ambitions, and more generally its colossal industrial overcapacity. These anxieties may encourage even more assertive enforcement of the UFLPA for strategic industries.

With China desperate to retain foreign investment and concurrently moving to beef up due diligence, multinationals are between a rock and a hard place. As supply chains bifurcate, companies may have to be more artful than ever in engineering the separation of their Chinese and non-Chinese business operations – and the origins of their parts.

Henry Storey is a senior analyst at Dragoman, a Melbourne-based political risk consultancy. He is also a regular contributor of The Interpreter published by The Lowy Institute.

To read the full article published by the Hinrich Foundation, click here.

The post US Sets Trade Policy Sights on China’s Xinjiang appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Trade Policy Tools for Climate Action /atp-research/trade-policy-tools-for-climate-action/ Thu, 30 Nov 2023 16:31:17 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=41024 In June 2022, at the WTO’s 12th Ministerial Conference (MC12), the entire WTO membership recognized that the world is facing “global environmental challenges including climate change and related natural disasters,...

The post Trade Policy Tools for Climate Action appeared first on WITA.

]]>
In June 2022, at the WTO’s 12th Ministerial Conference (MC12), the entire WTO membership recognized that the world is facing “global environmental challenges including climate change and related natural disasters, loss of biodiversity and pollution”. It also noted “the importance of the contribution of the multilateral trading system to promote the UN 2030 Agenda and its Sustainable Development Goals, in its economic, social, and environmental dimensions, in so far as they relate to WTO mandates and in a manner consistent with the respective needs and concerns of Members at different levels of economic development”. This acknowledgement came after an increased level of discussions at the WTO’s Committee on Trade and Environment (CTE) and other WTO bodies, and initiatives on how trade and trade-related policies could be harnessed and better aligned with climate objectives.

The WTO’s Environmental Database (EDB), available via the WTO website, shows that WTO members, from all regions and stages of development, are increasingly using trade-related policies as part of their climate action toolbox. From 2009 to 2021, members notified to the WTO more than 5,000 measures with climate-related objectives. About 40 per cent were notified by developing members. WTO bodies and notification tools offer extensive opportunities, therefore, for governments to exchange views and experiences, learn from each other and develop best practices on a range of trade-related policy tools that can contribute to effective climate action.

Following the publication of the WTO Secretariat’s 2022 World Trade Report, which focused on the complex relationship between trade and climate change, Trade Policy Tools for Climate Action seeks to highlight key trade-related policies being used, or that could be used, by governments to mitigate the effects of climate change or to adapt to its consequences.

The policy tools set out in this publication are simply intended to be a source of information and possible inspiration, amongst others, for policymakers to draw on in pursuit of their domestic climate mitigation and adaptation plans. They are purely voluntary in nature, and the publication does not seek to evaluate what the most appropriate or efficient policy tools might be for governments, individually or collectively.

As a contribution to the discussions at COP28, taking place in late 2023, on how trade can be a key part of the solution to the climate crisis, the aim of this publication by the WTO Secretariat is to provide information that will assist the debate going forward.

tptforclimataction_e

 

To access the summary, as well as a chapter directory posted by the WTO, click here.

To read the full publication, click here.

The post Trade Policy Tools for Climate Action appeared first on WITA.

]]>