Globalization Archives - WITA /atp-research-topics/globalization/ Thu, 26 Sep 2024 21:40:13 +0000 en-US hourly 1 https://wordpress.org/?v=6.6.1 /wp-content/uploads/2018/08/android-chrome-256x256-80x80.png Globalization Archives - WITA /atp-research-topics/globalization/ 32 32 Ten Quick Wins for: Re-globalization and Resilience in Trade /atp-research/ten-quick-wins/ Mon, 09 Sep 2024 20:53:15 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=50250 Foreword The year 2024 marks a global election cycle with over 80 countries, representing more than half of the world’s population casting their votes. In these uncertain times, the world...

The post Ten Quick Wins for: Re-globalization and Resilience in Trade appeared first on WITA.

]]>

Foreword

The year 2024 marks a global election cycle with over 80 countries, representing more than half of the world’s population casting their votes. In these uncertain times, the world finds itself confronted by a state of “polycrisis”—a complex web of interconnected global challenges that transcends borders. Geopolitics and international trade have a critical role to play in driving solutions to these crises. 

As many countries continue to navigate the aftermath of the COVID-19 pandemic, the world contends with other pressing issues such as the increasing urgency of tackling climate change and addressing the fragmentation of traditional geopolitical alliances. As nations confront various stressors, including ongoing conflicts in several regions around the world, these interconnected issues have heightened uncertainties and undermined the previously robust support for open trade.

Ten Quick Wins for: Re-globalization and Resilience in Trade

Quick Win No. 1

In the past three decades, the world has enjoyed numerous benefits of trade liberalization. For example, in the first 25 years since the establishment of the WTO average tariffs dropped from 10.5% to 6.4%, and the value of global trade nearly quadrupled. The emergence of a global supply chain seamlessly weaved goods and services from various corners of the world into products ready for consumers’ hands. However, disruptions in recent years, such as the COVID-19 pandemic, climate-change-related natural disasters, and geopolitical events, have exposed significant risks in the global supply chain model. These disruptions have propelled businesses to diversify their supply chains in order to mitigate disruption risks. This means increasing sourcing opportunities from a diverse geographical footprint.

Quick Win No. 2

Trade policy can significantly leverage re-globalization to achieve a net-zero world, but it is crucial to ensure these measures include developing countries, particularly the most vulnerable and marginalized. Climate science advocates for enhanced efforts to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions and move towards a sustainable energy future, as underscored by the 2023 Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) Synthesis Report. Agreements like the 2015 Paris Agreement and the 2021 Glasgow Climate Pact have set ambitious targets for net-zero carbon dioxide emissions by mid-century. However, developing countries often lack the financial resources, technological advancements, and institutional capacity to meet these targets. This risks their exclusion from the benefits of global climate initiatives such as carbon markets and clean energy transitions.

Quick Win No. 3

Workers are the backbone of international trade. They provide global services, the labor for tradable goods, and the means to ship exports and imports. Despite their unique importance to trade, not all workers are treated equally, and many groups are excluded from the design, implementation, and enforcement of trade policies. Countries should offer a seat at the trade policy table not only to advantaged trade union representatives but also to vulnerable workers who lack union representation.

Quick Win No. 4

The world is on the cusp of a transformative shift as the growth of clean energy and digital technologies propel humanity toward a minerals-based economy. This transformation holds the promise of a more sustainable and interconnected future, but it will also be highly material intensive. Meeting the burgeoning demand for these materials will necessitate an unprecedented expansion of mining activities. Experts estimate that the demand for lithium-ion batteries alone could require more than 300 new mines by 2035. Emerging green technologies will further accelerate demand for critical minerals needed for the generation and transmission of more renewable energy.

Quick Win No. 5

Cross-border data flows are crucial for trade and digital economy innovation. The rapid advancement and adoption of artificial intelligence (AI) further highlights the need to ensure that data flows freely, safely, and securely across borders. However, diverse and sometimes irreconcilable policy interests of WTO members have fueled the lack of agreement on vital issues, such as data governance, and slimmed down the negotiation agenda within the WTO’s Joint Statement Initiative on Electronic Commerce (E-Commerce JSI). These developments reflect ongoing concerns about shrinking policy space, privacy, national security, and data sovereignty, which can lead to regulatory fragmentation and restrictions on data flows. While AI is not currently included in the E-Commerce JSI, rapid developments in AI governance outside the WTO indicate the potential for further fragmentation. We propose a pragmatic approach focused on inclusivity through regulatory interoperability and technical harmonization, where certification frameworks and technical standards play a key role.

Quick Win No. 6

The WTO dispute settlement system is vital for enforcing WTO rules and providing security and predictability to the multilateral trading system. While the system has been by and large effective over the past 30 years, its practical application over time has made clear that some aspects need improvement or clarification. Accumulated dissatisfaction of some WTO members over certain features of the system, especially related to appellate review, led to a deadlock in the appointment of Appellate Body members to replace those whose terms of office had expired. This situation came to a head in December 2019, when the Appellate Body became non-functional due to a lack of quorum.

Quick Win No. 7

Responding to the perception that aspects of international trade create economic security risks, some WTO members have implemented unilateral, trade-inhibiting measures that lack clear endpoints. Members may justify violations of trade rules by invoking the WTO security exceptions, provided all requirements are met. However, security exceptions are not a long-term solution for persistent, unpredictable challenges and may even preclude multilateral approaches to anticipate and mitigate economic security risks. It is time to view security as more than an exception to WTO rules and principles. Members should build a new mechanism for economic security issues using the WTO’s safeguards procedures as a model.

Quick Win No. 8

Redirecting investment flows to developing and least-developed economies is one of the key challenges to overcome when thinking about a new paradigm for globalization and building resilience in trade. The Joint Initiative on Investment Facilitation for Development, launched by some WTO members in December 2017, aimed to address trade barriers that impede and restrict investment processes between countries. Although the conclusion of the negotiations on the Investment Facilitation for Development (IFD) Agreement was announced in February 2024, the Agreement was not incorporated into Annex 4 of the Marrakesh Agreement during the 13th WTO Ministerial Conference (MC13). Establishing these rules at the multilateral level is crucial to creating a cohesive and inclusive global investment environment, which will enhance the participation of developing and least-developed WTO members in global investment.

Quick Win No. 9

Across the globe, governments are increasingly confronting the urgent challenge of combating climate change. The green transition is essential to tackle this challenge and necessitates wide scale innovation and dissemination of advanced clean technologies. While the clean tech boom is underway, many developing countries are struggling to keep pace. The WTO is uniquely positioned to facilitate technology transfer by leveraging its existing frameworks and enhancing international cooperation with existing initiatives, such as those of the UNFCCC.

Quick Win No. 10

For decades, development finance has played a critical role in supporting financial resilience in developing countries. However, even countries that are striving to increase their economic strength remain vulnerable to external macroeconomic shocks and geopolitical uncertainties. One way development finance can help shield developing economies from shocks and drive inclusive growth is by championing the adoption of digital payments—including open and competitive payments markets and public-private partnerships.

TradeExperettes_10+Quick+Wins+for+Re-globalization+and++Resilience+in+Trade+FINAL-compressed
 
To read the report as it was published on the TradeExperettes webpage, click here.
 
To read the full report, click here.

The post Ten Quick Wins for: Re-globalization and Resilience in Trade appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Geopolitics is Corroding Globalization /atp-research/corroding-globalization/ Tue, 04 Jun 2024 13:50:14 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=46172 The following article was published in the June 2024 issue of the International Monetary Fund’s Finance & Development Magazine. To read the full F&D Magazine, click here.   How should...

The post Geopolitics is Corroding Globalization appeared first on WITA.

]]>
The following article was published in the June 2024 issue of the International Monetary Fund’s Finance & Development Magazine. To read the full F&D Magazine, click here.

 

How should the IMF respond?

As the IMF turns 80, its core macroeconomic mission still deserves to be pursued and prioritized. The ongoing corrosion of globalization—reinforcing and being reinforced by geopolitical fragmentation—increases the vulnerability of all but the largest economies to foreign economic shocks, arbitrary swings in current account balances, interruptions in access to dollar liquidity, and accumulation of unsustainable debt. The increasing politicization of international finance and commerce by China, the European Union, and the United States has, however, put at risk the IMF’s ability to assist member countries and limit exploitative behavior by the governments of the three largest economies. For the sake of global economic stability, the IMF must get out in front of these dangers.

But stability will not be achieved by broadening the institution’s remit in an effort to pander to the changing whims of the largest shareholders, though that response might be understandable as a short-term political approach. Instead, the IMF must emphasize its unique role as a multilateral conditional lender and a truth teller regarding international debt and monetary issues. This role justifies greater operational independence, along the lines of central banks.

First, the broader and more discretionary the core IMF agenda, the greater the vulnerability of member countries to the geopolitical machinations of large-economy governments and the market flows they influence—which is precisely the threat that is currently on the rise.

Second, broad consistency in both substance and process in dealings with member countries is critical to the legitimacy of the IMF’s decision making, especially when members are most vulnerable. Technocratic evenhandedness is essential to successful buy-in by all members over the long run, even at the expense of some local support in short run. Inconsistencies of the sort imposed by the US on successive programs with Argentina or by the EU’s “troika” role in the euro area crisis are likely to grow over time.

Third, although there are other international forums to address inequality, climate, and other global issues, only the IMF can be a quasi-lender of last resort and speaker of truth to economic power on debt and monetary issues. The IMF cannot put up substantial funds for longer-term development and global public goods—or mobilize private financing on an ongoing basis—as others can. It should be ready to trade its seat in these discussions for greater institutional (not just de facto) independence in its core mission.

We are likely at the early stage of a cycle of cross-border distrust among the big three economies feeding demands for self-reliance and then demanding that smaller economies choose sides. The IMF may have only a brief window to build its institutional strength before it is pressured recurrently to choose sides between major shareholders.

More central than ever

The IMF’s core macroeconomic mission is to address member nations’ vulnerabilities that arise through cross-border commerce and financial flows and manage the international monetary system that underlies those flows. In their recent assessment, Floating Exchange Rates at Fifty, Douglas Irwin and Maurice Obstfeld point out that many of the problems the IMF and the Bretton Woods agreements were designed to address are inherent to international finance. These problems remain, even though the postwar fixed exchange rate system was abandoned in favor of today’s non-system:

  • Exchange rate flexibility allows for monetary independence, yielding low inflation, but still does not prevent sudden stops and financial crises.
  • Foreign economic shocks are still transmitted, often with substantial effects on smaller and lower-income countries.
  • Capital flows often drive large rapid fluctuations in current account deficits.
  • Interruptions in the availability of dollar liquidity to member economies have major repercussions, sometimes causing financial crises.
  • Self-insurance efforts by large-surplus economies—whether through currency manipulation or replacement of imports with subsidies and tariffs—reduce global growth and impose adjustments during recessions on others.

As a result, there is no getting away from crisis lending with conditionality when member economies lose access to financial markets or suffer capital flight. The IMF’s ability to provide credible conditional adjustment financing, cushion groups of economies from common economic shocks, and restore access to market liquidity while restructuring international debt obligations is therefore more, not less, central than ever.

Only the IMF can provide this support on a multilateral, nearly universal basis. Any other institution or bilateral intergovernmental arrangement offering emergency financing will give that lender prejudicial influence over the borrowing country.

Benefits of surveillance

Surveillance of spillovers from the misguidedly excessive self-insurance policies of the largest economies, if consistently pursued, has a good shot at benefiting the global economy. Small achievable changes in the policies of those economies can aid many significantly, boost IMF credibility, and reduce risk. Similarly, by seeking to coordinate on cross-border debt and monetary issues, the IMF can generate benefit by influencing small changes in (or offsetting) behavior by lenders and reserve currency issuers. The more independent the IMF, the greater its legitimacy in its interaction with members.

The IMF must also call China, the EU, and the US to account through surveillance of their increasingly political and bullying control of access to their markets and its spillovers to the rest of the world. When China or the US conditions access to its payment systems or fossil fuel exports on national security goals, uncertainty reverberates through the rest of the world. Emerging markets’ growth prospects rise and fall as the big three economies arbitrarily determine who gets to produce their imports and who does not.

Let the other international economic and financial institutions—the World Bank, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, the Group of 20 major economies, and so on—take their seats at every arguably relevant table and maximize their funding. The IMF is the only multilateral institution that deals directly with cross-border spillovers and macroeconomic volatility. The IMF is the only multilateral institution that can engage in macroeconomic conditionality with any hope of legitimacy and of changing borrower policies. The IMF is the only international entity that can force negotiation, albeit not necessarily rapid restructuring, by private sector investors. And the IMF is the only international organization that can chide the big three economies in precise terms with respect to their policies and not just ask for more contributions to public goods.

In surveillance, as in lending and other policy decisions, the EU, the US, and China have a common interest in making sure that each is criticized according to the same criteria, with the same frequency, and through the same public channels. The IMF should lock in on independent frankness rather than a mutual nonaggression pact over US fiscal deficits, Chinese exchange rates, and the EU’s ill-timed austerity, which served the world so poorly in the 2000s and 2010s.

Confronting new challenges

To better achieve its mandated goals and shore up its legitimacy, the IMF should aim for greater operational independence, akin to that of most central banks, while maintaining external evaluation of its competence by its members and having them set its overall goals. This is already taking place to some degree with respect to executive board approval of specific program decisions, for example. Continued progress will likely require narrowing down the IMF’s mandate to its core functions in exchange for more autonomy in specific policy decisions. Yielding some turf is what the Fund must do in terms of governance deals without compromising its evenhanded treatment of members.

Given the growing distrust among the US, the EU, and China, there should be a way forward to a mutual agreement to give the IMF that operational insulation. Securing such an agreement, with clear limits on what the IMF can address, would assure each of the big three economies that the other two will not be able to exercise control in situations that really matter to them. All macroeconomic institutions depend upon such a mutual recognition that it is better to yield control to be confident that there will be no abuse of power in turn. The absence of adequate insulation of IMF operations will likely splinter the global financial safety net, with divergent politicized conditionality; allocate access to funding unevenly, if not unfairly; and diminish stability of the international monetary system.

By focusing on its core mission, the IMF can adapt to the new global economic challenges arising from the fragmentation of geopolitics and the corrosion of globalization. Particularly worrisome is the largest economies’ increasing tendency to link access to their markets to various political loyalty tests or side payments. All manner of access is affected—exports to those countries, employment and technical knowledge in high-tech and other industries deemed “critical,” financial services and liquidity, foreign direct investment into and from those countries, and cross-border aid and lending. Intentional or not, this is the kind of national-security-driven fragmentation that the creation of the Bretton Woods institutions 80 years ago was aimed to prevent.

There are of course other imminent global challenges: climate change first and foremost, but also pandemics, food security, technology competition, trade wars, real wars, and the mass migrations all these induce. For member countries other than the big three, these challenges are likely to be experienced as recurring, increasingly frequent macroeconomic shocks. To the extent that these are simultaneous shocks across many member countries, the IMF should provide special facilities or lending to those members on common terms and insist that the big three economies change their behavior or offset the shocks.

Exercising best practice

For the majority of its members, then, it is essential that the IMF’s advice on macroeconomic policies to manage shocks and the vulnerabilities they expose follow best practice, and is consistent for all members, whatever the source of the shock. This is in the long-term best interest of the big three economies as well. But their governments are increasingly tempted either to insert their geopolitical preferences into IMF decisions or to shield their protectionist self-dealing from surveillance, despite the large impact on others.

The IMF can thus best serve its membership—including the big three—as a bulwark of technocratic multilateralism against politicized bullying in financial and other market access. A significant step in this direction would be greater IMF executive board ability to pass decisions by qualified majority voting—meaning restriction of the largest shareholder’s ability to exercise a veto—except on long-term or quasi-constitutional issues. This exchange of narrowness for the sake of operational independence would be helpful because the IMF would not be putting more US taxpayer funds at perceived risk or using them to serve mission creep.

Another step forward would be to adopt stricter and more consistent rules limiting IMF lending to economies at war, for example, with respect to Israel, the West Bank and Gaza, and Ukraine today. There is, of course, a need for support and eventual reconstruction assistance, but if the IMF is seen as taking sides while conflict is ongoing, it may split the world economy even further. For the first time since the 1980s, military conflicts directly involving the major powers’ allies on opposite sides are occurring and are likely to continue. The IMF should forestall falling into this trap.

Beyond China, the US, and overrepresented EU economies, the IMF’s members, particularly low- and middle-income countries, should view these challenges as an opportunity to have more say on matters that affect them deeply. Enhanced operational independence would go hand in hand with continued IMF accountability to its board for evaluation of its policy execution and for goal setting. The Bretton Woods institutions must be more reliable in the coming years if the big three economies continue to retreat from rules-based globalization in favor of with-us-or-against-us exclusionary economics. For all the immediate pressure on the IMF, well intentioned or otherwise, to respond to its largest shareholders on any given issue, insulation from increasing geopolitical division would be more than prudent. Greater operational independence is the prerequisite for addressing any and all of the other global economic challenges as geopolitics corrodes globalization.

Adam Posen is president of the Peterson Institute for International Economics.

Posen

To read the full article as published by the International Monetary Fund, click here.

To read the full article, click here.

The post Geopolitics is Corroding Globalization appeared first on WITA.

]]>
The Conservative Case & The Progressive Case for Globalization /atp-research/cons-prog/ Thu, 30 May 2024 19:15:31 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=46043 As part of the Cato Institute’s 5-part series, Defending Globalization: Law and Politics, the following two essays were published on May 30th, 2024. “The Conservative Case for Globalization,” authored by...

The post The Conservative Case & The Progressive Case for Globalization appeared first on WITA.

]]>
As part of the Cato Institute’s 5-part series, Defending Globalization: Law and Politics, the following two essays were published on May 30th, 2024. “The Conservative Case for Globalization,” authored by Jeb Hensarling, can be found below. Following it is “The Progressive Case for Globalization” by Inu Manak and Helena Kopans-Johnson.

 

The Conservative Case for Globalization

Many self‐​styled conservative talking heads and members of Congress are calling for industrial policy, forms of wage and price controls, and new federal agencies to police free speech. Such positions have historically been anathema to the conservative movement and should remain so. Along with these issues, there is likely no other issue more timely or relevant to the question of just who is—and what is—a conservative than the issue of globalized free trade.

History

To settle the question of who may legitimately claim the title of “conservative” today, a quick reminder of the movement’s origins and evolution and their relation to trade is helpful. Although admittedly there is no universally held definition of conservatism, there have been broadly recognized and accepted core principles, as well a proud historical lineage. The English parliamentarian and philosopher Edmund Burke is generally recognized as the father of conservatism. Burke, throughout his career, advocated for freer trade. He understood that trade is not a zero‐​sum game between countries. In supporting reduced trade barriers between Britain and Ireland, Burke argued, “The prosperity which arises from an enlarged and liberal system improves all of its objects; and the participation of trade with flourishing Countries is much better than a monopoly of want and penury.”

His arguments included those based on economic utilitarian grounds. For example, he argued in Parliament that a free market without government interference is the best method to help the poor. As conservatives today continue to fight the rise of the social welfare state, they have historically recognized, as did Burke, that cost‐​increasing protectionism simply creates greater welfare dependency, not less.

Burke’s more impassioned and important argument, however, rested upon a recognition and reliance upon natural rights (conservatives should think, “We hold these truths to be self‐​evident …”). Burke believed that these rights clearly entitled and protected an individual’s right to both own property and to trade it freely.

For decades, most conservatives have proudly viewed themselves as free‐​market conservatives, a moniker whose principled intellectual foundation rests upon Adam Smith’s classic work An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Noteworthy, Smith was a friend and contemporary of Burke. Smith skewered the prevailing mercantilist and protectionist policies of the day and argued on utilitarian grounds that freedom of trade across international borders benefited the masses. He wrote, “Trade which, without force or constraint, is naturally and regularly carried on between any two places is always advantageous.” Some modern‐​day conservatives have now begun relying on the limited exceptions to the free trade rule (e.g., national defense) that Smith enumerated in his work to justify their protectionism. But any plausible reading of Smith indicates that these exceptions are just that—exceptions—which he further explained were rarely justified and often subject to abuse.

Today one of the greatest accolades within the conservative movement is that of “constitutional conservative,” a term meant to convey fealty to the Founding principles contained within the Declaration of Independence and US Constitution. Any conservative would be well advised to carefully reread the Declaration’s list of the repeated “injuries and usurpations” of the Crown, which evidenced its tyranny and justified American independence. The list includes “cutting off our Trade with all parts of the World.” Thomas Paine, author of Common Sense, the most influential pamphlet of the Revolutionary Era, wrote that to a trading country, freedom of trade was “of such importance, that the principal source of wealth depends on it; and it is impossible that any country can flourish … whose commerce is … fettered by laws of another.… A freedom from the restraints of the Acts of Navigation I foresee will produce … immense additions to the wealth of this country.”

In addition to Paine, most Founders believed in the goal of free trade and viewed it as necessary for the prosperity of the republic. They believed the principal and proper use of tariffs should be limited to revenue raising, not protecting domestic industries. In fact, at the dawn of our republic and for more than a century thereafter, the bulk of tax revenues were derived from import duties, given their relative ease of collection, as Phil Magness lays out in his Cato Institute essay on the history of tariffs in the United States between 1787 and 1934. The other recognized legitimate use of tariffs was to incentivize other nations to open their borders to our trade. These purposes are in distinct contrast to the purposes proposed by many today who seek to engage in industrial policy that benefits discreet economic sectors or industries or that promotes economic nationalism designed to severely limit or close off our international trade.

Article l, Section 8 of the Constitution unequivocally gives Congress the power to both “regulate Commerce with foreign Nations” and to “lay and collect Taxes, Duties.” Because of this section, some argue that conservatives stand on firm constitutional ground in favoring the imposition of tariffs. It should be noted that Section 8 also empowers Congress to borrow money. Given the magnitude and dangerous trajectory of the national debt, few conservatives believe the exercise of such power a wise one. The same is true for the imposition of tariffs.

Finally, the most conservative leader of the 20th century, President Ronald Reagan, confidently proclaimed that in America, “Our trade policy rests firmly on the foundation of free and open markets.” Although Reagan did implement some protectionist measures, they were part of his broader efforts to stave off even worse protectionism from Congress and to push for broader liberalization through the US‐​Canada Free Trade Agreement (the North American Free Trade Agreement’s [NAFTA’s] predecessor) and the US‐​Israel Free Trade Agreement, as well as launching negotiations that led to the creation of the World Trade Organization (WTO), the successor to the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). Trade doubled on his watch.

There has been debate over the use of tariffs ever since America became a constitutional republic. There have been times in our history when, regrettably, tariffs carried the day. And certainly, there have been tariffs enacted that have arguably fallen into Smith’s enumerated and limited exceptions. What isn’t debatable is that the conservative movement has always rested on a firm foundation of personal freedom, including economic freedom, based on natural rights, and at least in the post–World War II era, this has always included the freedom to trade.

Thirty‐​five years after Reagan, President Donald Trump tweeted, “The word TARIFF is a beautiful word indeed,” as he proceeded to impose 10–50 percent tariffs on steel and aluminum and a wide array of Chinese goods. He has now doubled down and called for a universal 10 percent tariff on all foreign‐​produced goods. Although conservatism has been the political movement supporting free trade for decades, a number of self‐​styled conservatives are now abandoning this long‐​held conservative principle and are finding common cause with both Trump and the majority of protectionist Democrats on the issue. They shouldn’t, and their arguments in doing so are unpersuasive.

National Security and Protectionism

The number‐​one argument proffered to support protectionism is one based on national defense. After all, even Adam Smith admitted that national defense considerations were, of necessity, one of the exceptions to the free trade rule. However, from my personal experience of serving 16 years in Congress, I know firsthand how often bad policy is wrapped in the cloak of national defense.

When Trump unilaterally imposed his steel and aluminum tariffs in 2018, he did so under the authority of Section 232 of the misnamed Trade Expansion Act of 1962. To exercise that authority requires a finding that the imports in question threaten to impair national security. However, in the same year that the tariffs were imposed, James Mattis, then secretary of defense, noted that only 3 percent of US production of steel and aluminum were actually needed for our armed forces. That begged the question of how, then, steel and aluminum tariffs were justified for everything from automobiles to beverage cans. Do some truly believe that a Toyota 4Runner or a can of Heineken beer threaten our national security?

Another example of the argument occurred during debate of the annual National Defense Authorization Act (NDAA). An amendment was offered to effectively force the military to buy only US‐​made running shoes for new recruits. Are running shoes critical to our national defense? Incidentally, the amendment would have had the effect of benefiting only one company: New Balance. It was argued that many running shoes sold in America are manufactured in China. True, but they also continue to be manufactured in Taiwan, Indonesia, Finland, Italy, and Thailand as well. Should running shoes truly become critical to the defense of our nation? Could we not stockpile them when global prices are cheap? In a time of war, would we be unable to ramp up our own production of running shoes? After all, during World War II we showed that we could ramp up domestic production of aircraft from just over 2,000 in 1939 to 300,000 by 1945. Hard to believe we’re incapable of doing the same for running shoes or an array of other goods in the 21st century.

During debate on another NDAA bill, an amendment was offered to force the military to only buy stainless steel flatware from domestic sources. In opposing the amendment during debate, House Armed Services Chairman Mac Thornberry (R‑TX) remarked, “I just don’t think that the knives and forks we use qualify as vital national security.” What does negatively impact national security, though, is the needless depletion of national wealth that occurs every time the government fails to buy the best product at the most economical price.

Washington undoubtedly has legitimate concerns over supply chain reliance on China for products with a clear national security nexus. But many companies are already in the process, or have completed, a reengineering or relocation of their supply chains, and with additional conservative tax and regulatory policies, even more would do so. Importantly, there remains a whole host of export controls, foreign direct investment approvals, and defense procurement requirements to help meet the threat that China poses. When it comes to our national defense, clearly the Trump administration’s tariffs didn’t mute China’s saber rattling, its defense buildup, or its incursions into the South China Sea to threaten Taiwan.

As an aside, it needs to be noted that, in almost all respects, the tariffs imposed on Chinese goods by the Trump administration failed. The trade deficit, which remains a most misleading statistic but one favored by the former president, actually worsened during the Trump administration. Furthermore, tariffs proved to be a two‐​way street—as they usually do. Just ask the Midwest farmers who suffered massive losses from retaliatory tariffs from China and had to be bailed out with $28 billion of subsidies from the US taxpayer. Finally, it could not be clearer that the tariffs not only had no impact on weakening China’s military, but they also clearly had no impact on China’s human rights abuses or its carbon footprint.

More often than not, the national defense argument for protectionism is unjustified and should never become a pretext for the abandonment of free trade in favor of industrial policy, corporate welfare, and protectionism. These all harm economic growth and innovation and consequently harm our national defense.

Additionally, although trade does not guarantee peace—Russia’s gruesome invasion of Ukraine even though the two nations have a fair amount of two‐​way trade, for example—there is clear evidence that trade ties tend to reduce armed conflict between countries. This is consistent with what pro‐​market Enlightenment philosophers argued. Beginning in the aftermath of World War II, the United States used trade as a tool to enhance national security. It has been nearly 80 years since major world powers engaged in a major war—a period of relative peace that has coincided with the establishment of the US‐​led global trading system.

Likewise, trade can be an immense tool for American soft power. It helps spread American values and it enriches allies. In the early 1990s, Mexico was facing a policy choice: it could either continue down the path of protectionism and heavy government intervention, or it could move “toward decentralized, democratic capitalism.” The George H. W. Bush and Bill Clinton administrations understood that by better integrating the Mexican economy into the United States’ economy, NAFTA could nudge Mexico away from the false allure of socialism. On top of the economic benefits of NAFTA, the agreement was a foreign policy success. Although certainly not perfect, and despite some recent backsliding, Mexico today is more committed to binding and predictable international trade and investment rules than it was in the 1980s and early 1990s.

Too often trade is viewed as weakening America’s national security when in fact it’s usually the opposite.

Trade, the Working Class, and Domestic Manufacturing

Another prominent argument offered by self‐​styled conservatives is that free trade somehow hurts the working class. Conservatives undoubtedly consider the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017 (TCJA) to be the crowning achievement from when Republicans last governed. Yet many who heralded its pro‐​growth tax relief for working families turned around and supported tax increases on these very same families in the form of tariffs.

Countless studies have shown that almost all the costs of the tariffs initiated under the Trump administration were borne by consumers and businesses. At worst, these costs may have offset most of American households’ average savings from the TCJA. For example, the cost of a washing machine increased an average of $86 just months after tariffs were imposed on them. According to the American Action Forum, all those tariffs combined have now increased consumer costs approximately $51 billion a year. Some tax cut. To make matters worse, the Tax Foundation calculates, based on current levels of imports, that Trump’s universal 10 percent tariff proposal represents a whopping $300 billion tax increase. Just when did tax increases become popular among conservatives?

Today, most blue‐​collar workers work in services, not manufacturing, and their greatest concern is not the loss of their job due to foreign competition, it is the loss of buying power from a paycheck that has shrunk in the face of historic inflation. I doubt many so‐​called elites shop at Walmart, but many working people certainly do. If a customer buys a Zebco fishing rod there it has been produced in China, and if they pick up a pair of Cowboy Cut Wrangler jeans, they’ll likely have come from Bangladesh. Although Walmart doesn’t like to advertise the fact, it remains the nation’s largest importer, with its shelves stocked with tons of foreign‐​produced goods that help working families make ends meet. Tariffs wouldn’t bring back manufacturing jobs that produce fishing rods or blue jeans; they’d only make those products more expensive.

Closely related to the working‐​class harm argument is the loss of manufacturing jobs argument that others refer to as a “hollowing out” of the industrial heartland. Indeed, manufacturing employment as a percentage of the workforce has decreased dramatically over the past several decades. But contrary to popular belief, those jobs have not been lost to hamburger‐​flipping jobs but instead to transportation, warehousing, construction, health care, tech, communications, finance, and other service‐​oriented parts of our economy—industries that benefit from open trade and whose jobs pay far more than those in low‐​skill manufacturing. America’s comparative advantages in these industries is one of the reasons why we are the world’s number‐​one exporter of services and continuously run a services trade surplus.

The dominant factor in the loss of domestic manufacturing jobs is not foreign competition but instead productivity. For example, according to the American Iron and Steel Institute, it took 10.1 hours to produce a ton of steel in 1980; today it takes only 1.5 hours. There may be fewer manufacturing workers today, but because of productivity gains, they are better compensated. According to the Center for Strategic and International Studies, the median income of the remaining US blue‐​collar manufacturing jobs has increased 50 percent in real inflation‐​adjusted terms between 1960 and 2019.

The reality is that tariffs harm most manufacturing jobs. Relatively open trade is vital for manufacturing and our defense industrial base. As the Cato Institute’s Scott Lincicome and Alfredo Carrillo Obregon document, around half of all goods imported are in fact intermediate goods, raw materials, and capital equipment used for domestic manufacturing. For example, many pipeline manufacturing companies import specialty casing that is necessary for oil and gas pipelines. Taxing these imports hurts workers at these companies or, if the higher costs are passed on, their energy‐​producing customers. How ironic for any conservative to call for an “all of the above” energy policy (one that supports the development and deployment of every form of energy) yet support making hydrocarbons more difficult and expensive to produce.

We could strengthen domestic manufacturing, the defense industrial base, and our energy sector by unilaterally eliminating tariffs on intermediate inputs, raw materials, and capital equipment. Doing that would truly put America first.

Trade, Family, and Community

Trade makes the necessities of life cheaper and more abundant for families. Walking through a grocery store reveals that a lot of our everyday food items are imported from around the world. This raises real incomes for Americans by increasing their purchasing power. Indeed, according to recent research from the Peterson Institute for International Economics, reduced friction in international transactions since the end of World War II—from trade liberalization and improvements in transportation and technology—increased US gross domestic product by $2.6 trillion in 2022 dollars, or about $7,800 per person and $19,500 per household. A 2016 study from two economists estimates that trade particularly benefited low‐​income consumers, who spend more of their income on items that were traded, including manufactured goods and food.

Although the gains over the last 75 years have been significant, there is more work to be done. Consider a family outfitting their kids to go back to school in the fall. As Bryan Riley of the National Taxpayers Union recently noted, backpacks face a 17.6 percent tariff and rulers face a 13.6 percent tariff; meanwhile, blue jeans face an 8.4 percent tariff and shoes face an average tariff of 10.8 percent. Eliminating these tariffs on basic family necessities would raise real incomes of American families.

Likewise, trade benefits communities and civil society. Because of relatively open trade, we can consume more for less and, as a result, we can work fewer hours, which means that it frees up time to participate in activities that build community, whether it’s volunteering, going to church, or coaching tee‐​ball. (The bats and tees are probably imported too.)

Moreover, although the media focuses on midwestern cities that hurt by import competition, there are countless stories about cities and towns that were once hurt by imports but that now thrive, in large part because of international trade. Take the border areas in Texas. They once had large concentrations of low value‐​added manufacturing. But according to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, “NAFTA, along with other market forces and technological change, created different jobs in Texas as low value‐​added manufacturing jobs were lost and as trade and investment increased. Border cities went on to gain far more employment than what they lost amid increased imports from Canada and Mexico and shifting production between the countries.” Indeed, economic integration has been enormously beneficial for Texas. The same Dallas Fed report notes, “A 10 percent increase in manufacturing on the Mexican side of the border increases employment 2.2 percent in Brownsville, 2.8 percent in El Paso, 4.6 percent in Laredo and 6.6 percent in McAllen.”

Conservatives have long argued that family and communities are the bedrocks of a free and prosperous society. Freer trade complements both. It’s surely not a cure‐​all for what ails our culture, but it helps. And the things that actually have hollowed out many American families and communities go way beyond economics. The underlying causes lie more in the realm of cultural changes and bad public policies, especially in the area of welfare. Tariffs can’t fix problems that trade didn’t cause.

Protectionism, Bureaucracy, and Rent Seeking

One of the great rallying cries of many conservatives remains “Drain the swamp!” But after the previous administration imposed its tariffs, it immediately empowered hundreds of Washington bureaucrats at the Department of Commerce and the Office of the US Trade Representative to grant individual waivers from these very same tariffs under what can at best be described as an opaque process with discretionary standards. As one company officer of a small pipeline manufacturer put it, “[Applying for a waiver] is a nightmare, like dealing with a lawyer and the IRS at the same time.” A schedule of tariffs doesn’t drain the swamp; it instead fills it with a cadre of well‐​connected lawyers, lobbyists, and special interests to work a system run by Washington bureaucrats.

It is difficult to comprehend how one can proudly wave the Gadsden flag, proclaiming “Don’t Tread on Me,” and then seemingly turn around and remark, “But go ahead ‘swamp,’ take away my freedom and choose for me which products I’m allowed to buy.”

Others charge that global trade is inherently antithetical to American interests. Notwithstanding being polysyllabic, “globalization” is now treated as a four‐​letter word. Although “globalization” is not clearly defined, the word conveys to many not just a loss of American jobs but a loss of American interests, prestige, identity, and perhaps most importantly, a loss of American sovereignty. Undoubtedly what comes out of the vast array of international organizations and forums in which the United States participates has helped fuel these fears. Even if it is not harmful, US membership in many of these may be of dubious value to some conservatives. As one former Congressman said in private conversation, “Why do we continue to pay the UN to insult us when they’d likely do it for free?” Conservatives legitimately question whether it is truly in America’s interest to participate in global conferences and organizations such as the United Nation’s Climate Change Conference, the Inter‐​American Development Bank, and the International Trade Union Confederation.

What can’t be questioned, though, is that Article I, Section 1 of the Constitution still reads, “All legislative Powers herein granted shall be vested in a Congress of the United States …” (emphasis added.) What can’t be questioned, though, is that Article II, Section 2 still reads in part, “[The President] shall have Power, by and with the Advice and Consent of the Senate, to make Treaties, provided two thirds of the Senators present concur.” Whatever treaties we enter into, and whatever commitments we make to other countries or international organizations, are an exercise of US sovereignty, not the loss of such. And what we enter into, we can exit. The United States unilaterally terminated its first treaty in 1798 and has done so on many occasions since.

No nation‐​state or international body can compel us to do anything without our consent. Should we choose to walk away from an agreement or treaty, the other party or parties may, of course, then choose to treat us in ways in which we prefer to not be treated. But again, they simply cannot sanction us with fines or loss of property without our consent. Our elected officials may agree to be bound by certain international rules or obligations whenever they decide the mutual pledges of other nations are in our national interest. But whenever “We the People” disagree with those decisions, we have the opportunity to unbind ourselves by electing either a new president, a new Congress, or both.

When it comes to our trade relations, the WTO is singled out for usurping US sovereignty. It doesn’t. It is simply a voluntary organization of trading nations attempting to come to consensus on accepted trade rules. Once rules are agreed upon, the organization attempts to arbitrate and it makes rulings by interpreting those rules. The WTO itself doesn’t initiate action and has no ability to enforce dispute settlement rulings other than by authorizing a complaining (winning) member government to deny a responding (losing) member government some of the benefits of membership. The WTO is a most imperfect organization that is in constant need of reform. But it usurps no US sovereignty, and we have more global trade benefiting the United States because of it.

Conclusion

In the final analysis, the most important reason anyone calling themselves a conservative should remain committed to trade has nothing to do with economics. Instead, it has everything to do with securing “the Blessings of Liberty to ourselves and our Posterity,” something for which our Founders risked their lives, fortunes, and sacred honor. Trade should not be viewed as a matter of discretionary foreign policy or a lever to promote economic nationalism. And although the data and historic evidence is overwhelmingly convincing that trade leads to greater economic growth, ultimately trade remains an issue of personal freedom, specifically economic freedom and its relation to private property. To “Buy American” should not be a matter of where one buys. For conservatives, it should instead be a matter of how one buys, and that how is with freedom of choice. If the conservative movement is to still stand for freedom of speech, freedom of enterprise, and freedom to bear arms, as a matter of principle it must firmly and unequivocally stand for freedom of trade.

To read the full essay published by the Cato Institute, click here.

 

The Progressive Case for Globalization

Introduction

Globalization has transformed the world. Centuries ago, it brought exotic spices and wares to distant corners of the globe. More recently, it has allowed us to work, see our families, and live our lives despite the disruptions caused by a once‐​in‐​a‐​lifetime pandemic. Trade in particular is a major component of globalization, which has lifted over a billion people out of poverty, made us more productive, and contributed to peace. Despite this, globalization and trade are under attack.

US Trade Representative Katherine Tai argued that the traditional approach to trade, focused on economic efficiency, has contributed to “a race to the bottom.” Meanwhile, President Biden has been beating the drum for his Made in America approach, even if it harms ties with our allies. Defending President Biden’s “Invest in America” agenda, Heather Boushey, member of the president’s Council of Economic Advisers, stated that “the global trading system has not always been fair, not always delivered the promised benefits to our citizens, [and] too often favored large corporate interests over workers’ interests.” The administration has thus called for a “new Washington consensus” but still has not answered the question posed by Jake Sullivan: “How does trade fit into our international economic policy, and what problems is it seeking to solve?”

What is striking about these statements is how far removed they are from traditional progressive views on trade and globalization, namely, that domestic and international prosperity are interlinked, that trade institutions support the rule of law, and that globalization is a tool for advancing well‐​being among the poorest. Trade has thus been peripheral to the Biden administration’s foreign economic policy. The shift in Washington toward favoring protectionist policies over trade openness is not only bad policy, but for progressives now calling for a new approach to trade, it also cuts against the very goals they are trying to achieve.

Tariff Liberalization as a Progressive Project

Economic turmoil and global conflict during the first half of the 20th century prompted a bold rethink of the international order. President Franklin Delano Roosevelt led the charge, overcoming fractured views on trade within his own party. The pragmatic and strategic vision of his secretary of state, Cordell Hull, helped him recognize the necessity of international economic cooperation to generate peace and prosperity at home and abroad. Roosevelt saw firsthand the devastating economic and social consequences of the Great Depression and acknowledged the role of trade barriers in deepening the crisis.

In a 1936 speech in Buenos Aires, Roosevelt criticized countries for their “attempts to be self‐​sufficient,” which “led to failing standards for their people and to ever‐​increasing loss of the democratic ideals in a mad race to pile armament on armament.” He called these policies “suicidal” and lamented that despite the suffering they caused, “many … people have come to believe with despair that the price of war seems less than the price of peace.”

The United States was no stranger to such policies. As post–World War I reconstruction was underway, European producers reemerged in the international market, fueling competition as they increased their exports. In the United States, amid a backdrop of economic uncertainty, many advocated for restrictive trade remedies that eventually culminated in the 1930 Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act, which led to an average tariff increase of 20 percent. Though originally intended to shield the agricultural sector from foreign competition through targeted tariffs, congressional logrolling greatly expanded the scope of the act to cover a broad range of products.

Unsurprisingly, its implementation sparked retaliatory measures from US trading partners, which included tariffs and quotas on products primarily imported from American producers, as well as widespread boycotts of American goods. While American exporters faced higher barriers to market access abroad, American consumers saw increases of between 4 and 6 percent in the relative price of imports, further reducing purchasing power and raising the cost of living. Though the tariffs did not bring about the Great Depression, economic historian Douglas Irwin notes that they contributed to both a “severe deterioration in trade relations in the early 1930s” and a global embrace of trade protectionism.

On the campaign trail in 1933, Roosevelt lambasted President Herbert Hoover and Republican leaders for the Smoot–Hawley tariff, saying that “President Hoover probably should have known that this tariff would raise havoc with any plans that he might have had to stimulate foreign markets,” and that the tariff was “the road to ruin, if we keep on it!” Retaliation from US trading partners was a major concern, making it difficult to sell products even to “logical customers, your neighbors across the border.” Roosevelt had another idea, which came from Hull, for “a tariff policy based on reason … a tariff policy based in large part upon the simple principle of profitable exchange, arrived at through negotiated tariff, with benefit to each Nation.” While Roosevelt was primarily concerned with economic stability in the United States, he was aware that this could not be achieved alone. In fact, he quickly recognized the symbiotic relationship between domestic recovery and the health of global trade.

The challenge, however, was that FDR lacked the authority to reduce trade barriers because the Constitution vests Congress with the power to regulate foreign commerce. Roosevelt and Hull thus jointly urged Congress to adopt the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934 (RTAA), which, once passed, would empower the executive branch to negotiate tariff reduction agreements based on the principles of reciprocity and mutual benefit. Roosevelt explained that “by reducing our own tariff in conjunction with the reduction by other countries of their trade barriers, we create jobs, get more for our money, and improve the standard of living of every American consumer.” Furthermore, by increasing the authority granted to the executive branch, the RTAA reduced the impact of parochial interests in trade policy, since the president represented a national constituency.

Though many sensitive domestic industries retained trade protections, the RTAA marked a turning point in US trade policy. Not only did trade critics consider it to be fairly managed, it also found support among 71 percent of Americans. That did not mean its renewal did not face opposition in Congress, but as the United States entered the Second World War, sensible tariff policy became an instrument beyond domestic economic recovery and would serve as the foundation for a new international economic order guided by pragmatism, cooperation, and shared prosperity.

International Peace, Alliances, and the Rule of Law

Domestic economic recovery was not the only motivation for transforming the global economy defined by a liberalized trade regime. Rather, trade proponents strongly believed that deep economic integration would boost international peacebuilding and result in a freer, fairer world.

This idea is not new. In 1795, Immanuel Kant outlined how a constitution for civil law among nations could overcome the law of nature and create the conditions for perpetual peace. A key component of this was universal hospitality, which could make, among other things, “commerce with native inhabitants possible” so that “distant parts of the world can establish with one another peaceful relations that will eventually become matters of public law, and the human race can gradually be brought closer and closer to a cosmopolitan constitution.” The freedom to engage in commerce and avoid plunder was thus considered an important aspect of establishing a peaceful international community.

While the academic debate over the pacifying effects of international trade is ongoing, scholars agree that trade is an important variable that contributes to peace, though they place different weight on the explanatory power of liberal philosophy versus structural factors, such as liberal institutions, and the conditions under which the relationship is most salient. Reflecting on his own experiences, Hull described his personal realization of the idea that trade could lead to peace:

When the war came in 1914, I was very soon impressed with two points. The first was its terrific commercial impact on the United States. I saw that you could not separate the idea of commerce from the idea of war and peace.… And the second was that wars were often largely caused by economic rivalry conducted unfairly. I thereupon came to believe that if we could eliminate this bitter economic rivalry, if we could increase commercial exchanges among nations over lowered trade and tariff barriers and remove unnatural obstructions to trade, we would go a long way toward eliminating war itself.

Hull’s recounting provides further evidence for the argument that managing economic security concerns became a central issue for the architects of the postwar international order. One such way to address these concerns was through a framework of rules that would lower barriers to trade and provide for the peaceful settlement of disputes. The first step to achieve this was the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), which helped facilitate open trade relations based on the principles of reciprocity, nondiscrimination, transparency, and enforceability. At the launch of the GATT negotiations, Roosevelt made the case before Congress for why US participation was so important, noting that “the purpose of the whole effort is to eliminate economic warfare, to make practical international cooperation effective on as many fronts as possible, and so to lay the economic basis for the secure and peaceful world we all desire.”

By establishing a rules‐​based system, the GATT prioritized a predictable trade environment that would prevent the resurgence of the protectionist policies that worsened the economic instability and political conflicts of the first half of the 20th century. However, the GATT needed to be updated and expanded through successive rounds of negotiations that moved beyond simple tariff barriers. Another Democratic president was responsible for one of the most important rounds of GATT negotiations, which was eventually named after him—the Kennedy Round.

Prior to starting those talks, John F. Kennedy had secured authorization from Congress for additional tariff cuts up to 50 percent under the Trade Expansion Act of 1962. Upon signing the legislation, Kennedy remarked that “this act recognizes, fully and completely, that we cannot protect our economy by stagnating behind tariff walls, but that the best protection possible is a mutual lowering of tariff barriers among friendly nations so that all may benefit from a free flow of goods.” Kennedy argued that expanding trade would not only strengthen the US economic position but also bolster US alliances and, in doing so, help counter the threat posed by communism. He thus called the Trade Expansion Act “an important new weapon to advance the cause of freedom.”

International institutions were central to advancing these goals and supported a strong belief in the centrality of the rule of law and fairness that undergirds the progressivism movement. In a 1942 radio address, Hull explained why Americans should support US involvement in the war, stating that “liberty under law is an essential requirement of progress.” Liberty, to Hull, was “more than a matter of political rights.” In fact, he argued that the United States had “learned from bitter experience that to be truly free, men must have, as well, economic freedom and economic security.” Extending that internationally, Hull argued for “cooperative action under common agreement,” which “will enable each to increase the effectiveness of its own national effort.” Fifty‐​two years later, to mark the signing of the Uruguay Round Agreements Act that established the World Trade Organization (WTO), President Bill Clinton also made the case for “a fair and increasingly open world trading system that allows the free market to work and rewards the most productive people in the world,” as a means to “restore stability to the lives of the working people of our country.” Economic security at home, it was understood, required international institutions based on the principle of fair competition, which would facilitate access to economic opportunities.

An important way to assure fairness is to have a system of rules that applies equally to all and a means of recourse when those rules are violated. At the WTO, that has been the dispute settlement system, which allows countries to peacefully resolve trade disputes among themselves. What is truly amazing about this system is that even the smallest countries have access to it, and throughout most of the organization’s history, no country has seen itself as above the law.

A rules‐​based trading system was therefore always a precondition for economic interdependence that would be fair and accessible to all. Today, economic interdependence is still a core principle of liberal internationalism, though in Washington policy circles it has become less valued over time. Part of this stems from a loss of confidence in the rules‐​based order. President Biden’s national security adviser, Jake Sullivan, questioned “the premise that economic integration would make nations more responsible and open, and that the global order would be more peaceful and cooperative,” arguing that “Russia’s invasion of Ukraine underscored the risks of overdependence.” Tai shares this view, when in response to a question about how Russia’s invasion of Ukraine had upended the accepted wisdom of trade promoting peace, she said, “Peace is probably more necessary for prosperity than prosperity is for peace.”

Each of these arguments veers far from the progressive views toward trade and interdependence held by Roosevelt (whose portrait hangs above the fireplace in President Biden’s Oval Office), as well as other progressives. They also fail to understand the nuance in the trade‐​promotes‐​peace literature by arguing that the presence of any conflict disproves the theory that economic integration reduces the frequency and scope of conflict. Furthermore, as political scientist Daniel Drezner points out, complex interdependence made it difficult for Russia’s closest geopolitical ally, China, to provide strong public support for the war in Ukraine. In fact, he argues that China’s links to the global economy and Western countries in particular curbed its behavior by tipping the cost–benefit analysis to favor adopting a less prominent role in the war. The Russia–Ukraine war thus reveals that while interdependence does not eliminate all security concerns, the liberal international order still effectively constrains aggressive foreign policy behavior and fosters collective responses. This is precisely why, in his famous address at American University in 1963, Kennedy remarked that “even the most hostile nations can be relied upon to accept and keep those treaty obligations, and only those treaty obligations, which are in their own interests.” A material interest in accessing markets can thus moderate a country’s behavior.

The loss of faith in the power of interdependence as a restraint and the benefits of a system based on rules appears to be the new consensus in Washington, perhaps best executed by former president Donald Trump. Under his administration, the United States launched a series of trade wars that not only resulted in significant economic harm at home and retaliation that soured relations with our closest trading partners but also undermined the rules‐​based trading system. Though President Biden has made important strides in improving relations with our allies, on trade, he has largely preserved, and defended, some of Trump’s most controversial policy actions.

For example, when the metals tariffs that were applied for alleged national security concerns were found to violate international trade rules, Adam Hodge, who was then a spokesperson for the US Trade Representative, denounced the ruling, saying that “the United States strongly rejects the flawed interpretation” of the rules and that “issues of national security cannot be reviewed in WTO dispute settlement.” To make the US objection clear, he went on to say, “We do not intend to remove the Section 232 duties as a result of these disputes.” What is interesting about the Biden administration’s position is that in saying its actions are above the law, the United States has now established a slippery slope whereby other countries can claim national security interests as cover for trade protectionism.

The US approach to trade has shifted far from its progressive roots in another important way as well. The spirit of cooperation and need for predictability that underscored the postwar institution‐​building efforts are also under threat, not just with adversaries but with allies too. Discussing the sunset review of the United States‐​Canada‐​Mexico Agreement, Tai stated that “the whole point” of the negotiations “is to maintain a certain level of discomfort, which may involve a certain level of uncertainty.” During the Trump administration, uncertainty was a driving strategy of trade policy.

The problem with uncertainty, however, is that it breeds confusion, economic disruption, loss of trust, and hesitancy over making commitments. This is the direct opposite of what motivated the architects of the modern international trading system and its most steadfast champion, the United States. The last expression of those progressive ideals was shared by former US Trade Representative Michael Froman in his exit memo, where he wrote: “Through our trade policy, we bolster our partners and allies, lead efforts to write the rules of the road for fair trade among partners, and promote broad‐​based development. Trade done right is essential for our economy here at home and for America’s position in the world.” In contrast, US policymakers today have increasingly embraced a more zero‐​sum logic and thus failed to appreciate the importance of leading by example on trade and other foreign economic policies.

Tackling Poverty and Promoting Shared Prosperity

Though many advocates of trade protectionism today often point to levels of global inequality, stalled development, and middle‐​class stagnation as justifications for de‐​globalization, the evidence paints a more positive picture of globalization. In fact, looking at indicators such as life expectancy, infant mortality, literacy, and living standards, the story of the era of globalization is one of considerable progress and declining inequality.

From 1990 to 2019, the share of the global population living below the poverty line—set at $2.15 per day based on 2017 prices—decreased from 38.01 percent to 8.98 percent. Economist Kimberly Clausing explains that within China alone, “the share of the population living in poverty fell from 88 percent of the population to 2 percent of the population between 1980 and 2012,” suggesting that a billion people were lifted out of extreme poverty due to China’s economic opening. The negative correlation between trade openness and poverty levels is difficult to dispute, especially considering that regions with the most stagnant economic growth are those that maintain high tariff barriers and have therefore seen slow trade growth, such as sub‐​Saharan Africa. In addition to reducing poverty, expanded trade led to increased gross domestic product (GDP) growth. Economists Gary Hufbauer and Megan Hogan estimate that without post–World War II trade liberalization, US GDP would have been $2.6 trillion lower in 2022, at $22.9 trillion instead of $25.5 trillion, averaging to welfare gains of $19,500 per household in 2022. These gains from trade have broadly benefited consumers and reduced inequality. The Cato Institute’s Chelsea Follett explains that this time period has also witnessed considerable progress toward raising living standards worldwide.

While small changes to tariff rates may appear inconsequential, the WTO estimates that universal withdrawals from free trade agreements and increases in most‐​favored‐​nation tariff rates would decrease real income by 0.3 percent and 0.8 percent within three years, respectively. The 6 percent increase in food prices in the United Kingdom following Brexit offers a potent example of this effect, when the cost of living increased 50 percent more for low‐​income households compared to high‐​income households. Critically, these costs were not evenly distributed, as lower‐​income households spend a higher portion of their income on imported items than high‐​income households.

Worsening this disproportionate effect is the fact that trade barriers raise the cost of goods and services and reduce the choices available to consumers. Recently, the 2024 Economic Report to the President highlighted that US imports from China were “accompanied by a substantial fall in US consumer prices, with disproportionate benefits accruing to low‐ and middle‐​income households because they have higher shares of tradable goods like food and apparel in their consumption baskets.” In the United States, it’s particularly striking that cheaper consumer goods typically maintain higher tariff rates than equivalent luxury products.

Ed Gresser, vice president and director for trade and global markets at the Progressive Policy Institute, identified this trend across the US tariff schedule and found, for example, that the tariff rate placed on steel spoons is five times higher than the rate placed on silver spoons. Similarly, while a cashmere sweater has a 4 percent tariff rate, wool sweaters have a 17 percent rate, and acrylic sweaters have a 32 percent tariff rate. This makes the US tariff schedule a regressive tax whereby low‐​income households are not only spending a higher portion of their income on imported items, but they are also paying a higher average tariff rate on those purchased goods. A growth in protectionist measures would exacerbate these inequities.

However, since the gains from trade are often diffused throughout the economy, they can often go unnoticed and are given less attention than trade costs, which are often concentrated. As a case in point, the “China Shock” serves as a common talking point for critics of globalization, even though the findings of the famous study that coined the term have been strongly contested.

In placing so much emphasis on concentrated and marginal direct employment losses, globalization’s critics also fail to see the widespread economic benefits of trade through greater competition with foreign producers, which results in lower prices for consumers and limits domestic firms’ ability to pursue monopolies, as Clausing explains in her book, Open: The Progressive Case for Free Trade, Immigration, and Global Capital. On the other hand, Clausing also calculates that “protectionist measures cost consumers as a group, on average, over $500,000 per job saved” through added taxes caused by higher tariffs. In some industries this cost is more extreme; according to economist Anne Krueger, “it is estimated that the annual cost of one job ‘saved’ in the steel industry is about $900,000.” These unemployment‐​based evaluations also ignore that lower tariff rates reduce the costs of intermediate goods for domestic manufacturers, which in turn leads to greater production capacity and hiring ability. Final made‐​in‐​America products are thus cheaper because of these foreign intermediate inputs, increasing their market competitiveness.

Clausing thus analogizes the trade shock to technology shocks: While advances in technology can reduce the demand for some jobs, they simultaneously increase productivity and efficiency, create many new job opportunities, and benefit everyday users. It would be unusual to come across someone who would argue that the internet should not have been broadly adopted for the sake of conserving a small portion of jobs. This is not to suggest that these shocks are not serious policy concerns; rather, it is intended to demonstrate that imposing protectionist measures to save jobs will fail to achieve the desired effect and instead will reduce economic growth and impose widespread costs. Broadly speaking, these negative externalities should be remedied through more robust public policy instead of trade restrictions to assist Americans in adjusting to economic disruptions.

As one of the report’s authors, Gordon Hanson, later remarked in Foreign Affairs, though the China Shock “hurt many US workers and their communities … so, too, have automation, the Great Recession, and the COVID-19 pandemic. And because the scarring effects of job losses are the same whether imports, robots, or a virus is responsible, responses to the damage should not depend on the identity of the culprit.” He therefore argued that protectionist measures “will do little to help workers who are already hurting or to help others avoid a similar fate” and that instead, the president “should establish targeted domestic programs that protect workers from the downsides of globalization.”

Though trade generally acts as a positive force, challenges persist. The economic disruptions and global health crisis caused by the COVID-19 pandemic drove many countries, including the United States, to grow wary of globalization, leaning away from international trade cooperation in favor of a more protectionist and at times fragmented system. However, the presumption that the optimal solution to these global challenges lies solely in unilateral or regional action is flawed. As WTO director‐​general Ngozi Okonjo‐​Iweala noted in the World Trade Report 2023, “a retreat from economic integration would roll back recent development gains, make it harder for countries to grow their way out of poverty, and harm future economic prospects for the poorest people the most.” In other words, fragmentation would only exacerbate existing challenges.

The World Trade Report instead advocated for addressing the world’s most pressing challenges through greater global openness, integration, and cooperation, contingent on the reform of the international trading system. This approach, termed “re‐​globalization,” aims to integrate more economies into the global trading system and to promote a more equitable, transparent, and reliable trading framework. As President Barack Obama once stated, “globalization is a fact,” and while the United States can’t “build a wall” around globalization, he said, “what we can do is to shape how that process of global integration proceeds so that it’s increasing opportunity for ordinary people.”

The United States has long shaped that process. In fact, it was American leadership in the global economy that established the WTO, which President Clinton described as “a victory for a couple of simple ideas.” Essentially, “the idea that America can lead in the 21st century, that we need not fear competition, that we want our neighbors to do better than they have been doing, and when they do better, we will do better.” Though the belief that a rising tide can lift all boats is no longer in vogue in Washington, it has been a driving force for US engagement in the world economy and has contributed to a healthier, wealthier, and more stable world.

Conclusion

US leadership in the global economy is needed now more than ever, yet there is no need to rethink the entire trading system. The blueprint is well known, and as this essay shows, the driving force behind the modern trading system is deeply rooted in American values. Many progressives have called this system unfair. No institution is perfect, and it is true that the WTO and US trade agreements as we have known them would benefit from reform. However, their critics have lost sight of the very real benefits globalization and trade have provided and have also forgotten the progressive ideas that helped shape the international trading system after the Second World War. That system has not only reduced poverty but has also promoted shared prosperity, at home and abroad. Progressives would do well to remember these achievements and their important part in securing them.

To read the full essay published by the Cato Institute, click here.

The post The Conservative Case & The Progressive Case for Globalization appeared first on WITA.

]]>
The Art of the Mini-Deals: The Invisible Part of EU Trade Policy /atp-research/mini-deals-eu-trade-policy/ Fri, 06 Oct 2023 04:00:36 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=39924 In a book that spent several weeks on the New York Times bestseller list, a former US president said: “I like thinking big. I always have. To me it’s very...

The post The Art of the Mini-Deals: The Invisible Part of EU Trade Policy appeared first on WITA.

]]>
In a book that spent several weeks on the New York Times bestseller list, a former US president said: “I like thinking big. I always have. To me it’s very simple: If you’re going to be thinking anyway, you might as well think big.”

Despite this inspirational quote, most of the trade deals pursued by the Trump Administration were not “big deals”. In contrast, most free trade agreements (FTAs) signed by countries around the world – the kind of trade agreements that nowadays capture people’s interest and political attention – are quite big. First, FTAs are big for they cover trade flows worth billions, and “essentially all products”, to use a well-known expression. The best proof for this assertion is that EU bilateral FTAs cover 52% of extra-EU exports. Hence, almost by default, FTAs are seen as important trade policy instruments as they eliminate tariffs affecting billions of euro worth of commercial interests. FTAs are a “big deal” also for other reasons beyond tariffs: for instance, if and when they open up new market access for services. Furthermore, FTAs cover many important areas such as sanitary and phytosanitary (SPS) measures, technical barriers to trade (TBTs), intellectual property rights (IPR) and public procurement. The red thread linking all these areas in an FTA is the overarching objective of trade facilitation and reduction in trade costs. Hence, FTAs are central to the widely accepted view of current global trade relations, governed essentially by multilateral rules established at the WTO and complemented by a large (and growing) number of FTAs.

This paper goes beyond the conventional wisdom and sheds light on other trade agreements (trade mini-deals), which so far were less in the focus of EU trade experts and academics. The paper offers a first, preliminary assessment and a taxonomy of these mini-deals. The main takeaway is that there is a lot more going on than what meets the eye when it comes to EU trade policy. In reality, FTAs are just the tip of the trade policy iceberg. When taking a systematic look, it becomes apparent that FTAs are only one of the many trade policy instruments. Beyond FTAs, the EU has signed a much larger number of trade mini-deals that have, potentially, a significant impact on EU trade. A corollary of this proposition is that, over time, the cumulative impact of these mini-deals may be very significant. The paper concludes with a short assessment of the role such mini-deals could play in the future, given the evolving nature of trade policy objectives and the growing complexity of international trade negotiations.

ECI_23_PolicyBrief_11-2023_LY03 (1)

To read the summary, please click here.

To read the full policy brief from the European Centre For International Political Economy, please click here.

The post The Art of the Mini-Deals: The Invisible Part of EU Trade Policy appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Can the World Trade Organization Act as a Bulwark Against Deglobalization? /atp-research/wto-as-bulwark-against-deglobalization/ Mon, 02 Oct 2023 16:00:10 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=41299 The following is an excerpt from the Simon J. Evenett’s article: Can the World Trade Organization Act as a Bulwark Against Deglobalization?  from Asian Economic Policy Review published by John...

The post Can the World Trade Organization Act as a Bulwark Against Deglobalization? appeared first on WITA.

]]>
The following is an excerpt from the Simon J. Evenett’s article: Can the World Trade Organization Act as a Bulwark Against Deglobalization?  from Asian Economic Policy Review published by John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd on behalf of Japan Center for Economic Research.

Abstract

Whether existing multilateral trade commitments really deter larger trading nations from taking steps that further weaken cross-border commercial ties is assessed here. Evidence from salient commercial policy episodes of recent years is combined with information on the actual leeway available to G-20 members under extant World Trade Organization rules. The upshot is a bleak assessment of the capacity of the existing multilateral trade rule book to rein in any attempt by larger trading nations to “deglobalize” the world economy.

Introduction

After the Global Financial Crisis analysts debated whether globalization – the ever-greater integration of national markets – was slowing down. Recently, the debate has shifted to whether the world economy has entered a phase of deglobalization. In light of growing geopolitical tensions and the so-called Polycrisis, some have gone so far as to argue that deglobalization – taken here to mean the conscious thinning of cross-border commercial ties through state action – is necessary.

My goal here is not to assess whether the world economy is or has been deglobalizing. Nor is my purpose to assess whether deglobalization is desirable or what its end point might be. Nor will I consider the factors that have triggered discussions of deglobalization. Here, I ask a different question: If a government contemplated trade policy measures that markedly thinned cross-border commercial ties, would the current corpus of multilateral trade rules prevent them from doing so? In short, I will examine what contemporary evidence reveals about the degree to which World Trade Organization (WTO) rules can really act as a bulwark against deglobalization.

The approach taken in this paper is not to assume or contend that existing multilateral trade rules have no bite. Demonstrating such a strong proposition is unnecessary given my research objective. Rather, I will marshal enough evidence on actual contemporary commercial policy decisions and on the leeway afforded to governments in current WTO accords that might give a reader inclined to believe that existing multilateral trade rules will act as an effective bulwark against deglobalization second thoughts. If this argument is correct then, as geopolitical rivalries intensify, we should moderate our expectations as to what WTO accords can deliver and look elsewhere for centripetal forces that might hold the world trading system together.

Assessment: Current WTO Rules cannot Contain Pressures to Deglobalize

The evidence presented in this paper implies that we should moderate our expectations as to the extent to which existing multilateral trade rules can limit state-induced deglobalization. Earlier, it was argued the WTO rule book is incomplete – for example, there are no rules on digital trade. Rules on foreign direct investment are patchy. Even where multilateral trade rules have been agreed, they allow many governments significant leeway to fragment markets (recall the size of the import tariff binding overhangs), or contain exceptions (recall the Article XI exceptions and those pertaining to national security) or they can be honored more in the breach (recall the evidence on the build-up of corporate subsidies) seemingly with impunity. Even when the rules were subject to dispute settlement, foundational principles – such as the MFN tariff treatment – have been simply ignored by major trading nations.

The best that can be said about the current multilateral trade rule book is that, to date, many governments (of mainly small- and medium-sized economies) have chosen not to openly violate their commitments. Pressures to favor national interests have been channeled away from transparent forms of trade discrimination (such as import tariffs) to less transparent forms of selective intervention (corporate subsidies, government procurement measures, export controls, and the like.) This shift toward harder to detect and less closely observed commercial policy intervention may have created the impression of a system capable of deterring government steps that fragment markets. If that was the case, the public revocation of MFN tariff treatment for most of China’s exports by the USA shattered that illusion. China’s retaliation and the enduring breach of the MFN principle have not been lost on observers either. Furthermore, the manner in which governments reacted to the crises of recent years and to intensifying geopolitical rivalry suggest little interest among the larger trading nations in returning to rules of the game agreed at the end of the Uruguay Round 30 years ago.

That multilateral trade rules are not likely to be an effective bulwark against conscious efforts to fragment markets or to offers of inducements to move factories across borders does not imply that these are desirable policy interventions. Indeed, that so many governments have chosen not to abandon the MFN principle, and that dozens of WTO members chose to lower trade barriers on medical goods and food during the crises of recent years, suggests that unilateral commercial policy is not always moving in a discriminatory direction. My conclusion here is that, for better or for worse, we have reached a point where governments have options that are no longer meaningfully constrained by multilateral trade rules. Of course, these findings make a mockery of the mantra that governments have insufficient policy space.

In principle, groups of like-minded nations could deter state-led deglobalization within the group – although that proposition ought to be evaluated on a case-by-case basis. Perhaps the expansion of membership of the Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership (CPTPP) can secure an oasis of less-distorted trade among its members? But creating an oasis does not address the root causes of the growing impotence of multilateral trade rules evidenced in this paper. Still, should compliance with multinational trade rules weaken further, one option available to governments is to seek to substitute lost multilateral market access with an expanded and deeper network of regional trade agreements.

If multilateral trade rules cannot do the job of discouraging policy-induced deglobalization, what can? The decisive battles over unilateral policy will take place in national capitals. With intensifying geopolitical rivalry, we can reasonably expect that national security and foreign policy officials are likely to play a greater role in shaping commercial policymaking. Too many of the former cross-border commercial ties are said to be a source of risk, so little discouragement to deglobalize can be expected from that quarter. For these officials, trade policy is, at best, part of second order diplomacy, to be invoked symbolically and not because of any expectation that curbing trade will actually change a foreign government’s actions. One potential source of countervailing power comes from that part of the business community which has a significant stake in an open global trading system. Whether enough senior executives are willing to do so is an open question.

 

Can the World Trade Organization Act as a Bulwark Against Deglobalization_

 

To read the full research article as it was published in Wiley Online Library, click here.

To read the full research article, click here

The post Can the World Trade Organization Act as a Bulwark Against Deglobalization? appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Digital Trade in Services: Globalization’s Exciting New Frontier /atp-research/digital-trade-services-globalization/ Tue, 26 Sep 2023 19:58:12 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=40294   Digitalization is allowing more services than ever to be traded internationally.   Digital Trade in Services Is Good for America The United States is a powerhouse in services and especially...

The post Digital Trade in Services: Globalization’s Exciting New Frontier appeared first on WITA.

]]>

 

Digitalization is allowing more services than ever to be traded internationally.

 

Digital Trade in Services Is Good for America

The United States is a powerhouse in services and especially digital‐​friendly services. U.S. services exports grew from $563 billion in 2010 to $897 billion in 2022, a 42 percent increase. A lot of that growth either is or could be connected to digital technology. More than 80 percent of U.S. services exports could, at least in principle, be delivered digitally. In 2020, U.S. exports of information and communication technology–adjacent services totaled $520 billion. Export growth has been especially strong in cloud computing and data services ($397 million in 2010 to $6.9 billion in 2021), computer services ($10.1 billion to $45.2 billion), research and development ($22.2 billion to $47.2 billion), and professional services ($48.7 billion to $132.5 billion).

The other things to keep in mind are that the digital economy is large and growing and that services are a much larger portion of the overall economy than goods. In 2019, the digital economy was roughly a 10th of American gross domestic product, and from 2005 to 2019, it grew at more than double the rate of the nondigital economy. Roughly two‐​thirds of the global economy and more than three‐​quarters of the American economy are services, not goods. The growth potential for digital trade in services is enormous. The more that services can be traded internationally, the more customers American service firms have access to.

Some of the most high‐​profile American businesses that benefit from this are the Big Tech firms: Apple, Microsoft, Amazon, Google, and Meta. These are five of the most important companies in the American economy—and arguably the world. The more of their services that they can sell abroad (e.g., Microsoft and Amazon’s cloud computing, Google’s search and advertising, Apple’s media content, and Meta’s social media and WhatsApp), the better it is for those firms’ workers and shareholders, most of whom are American. Those benefits then spread to the wider economy; one technology sector job supports, on average, five other jobs in the economy. A worker at one of these businesses, or any other business that can better sell its services globally, has more disposable income that they can then spend on local goods and services. Moreover, millions of Americans’ retirement savings plans, such as a 401(k), include one or more of these companies’ stocks. These firms contribute significantly to the U.S. tax base, and they provide services that delight consumers, often for free. There are a lot of ways in which the success of these companies strengthen America. To the extent that U.S. policy encourages more globally liberalized trade in services and thus helps these companies succeed, those policies make America better.

Moreover, the benefits of digital services do not merely accrue to this small handful of firms but are instead (and encouragingly) widely dispersed throughout the economy. In 2022, Apple’s App Store facilitated over $1 trillion in commerce, more than double what it did in 2019. Cloud computing is another good example. As the Congressional Research Service notes, “One driver of the diffusion of the benefits of the internet and digitization has been cloud computing. Cloud services have been called the great equalizer, since they generally allow small companies access to the same information and the same computing power as large firms using a flexible, scalable, and on‐​demand model.” Not only that, but digital services increasingly undergird the movement of physical goods. For example, in 2018, Walmart partnered with IBM to create a blockchain‐​enabled food traceability system that helps prevent foodborne illness outbreaks. Manufacturing increasingly comes packaged with services, many of which are digital in nature, that add considerable value. So, for example, a manufacturing firm might hire another firm to do product design or supply chain optimization; those services end up embedded in the value of the product, but the design expertise and supply chain expertise are communicated across borders digitally. These services add value to the manufactured product while also reducing costs. Service exports also support jobs (e.g., 98,800 jobs in Michigan, 73,000 jobs in Missouri, 32,300 jobs in Kentucky, 46,200 jobs in Utah, and 116,000 jobs in Ohio). All told, service exports support 5.3 million American jobs.

Gary Winslett is an Assistant Professor of Political Science, Middlebury College.

To read the full publication, click here.

The post Digital Trade in Services: Globalization’s Exciting New Frontier appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Globalization and International Value Chains: 2000-2021 /atp-research/globalization-international-value-chains/ Tue, 28 Feb 2023 19:10:59 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=36153 The disruptions in international supply chains that occurred during the COVID-19 pandemic and the escalation of economic and political tensions between the U.S. and China have given rise to claims...

The post Globalization and International Value Chains: 2000-2021 appeared first on WITA.

]]>
The disruptions in international supply chains that occurred during the COVID-19 pandemic and the escalation of economic and political tensions between the U.S. and China have given rise to claims that globalization has died or is at least moribund. In this note we will address three questions concerning the evolution of globalization from 2000 through 2021:

1. Did globalization decline during that period?
2. To what extent did North America and China decouple their supply chains?
3. Did regionalization (“nearshoring”) increase?

In its broadest sense, the term “globalization” captures the interaction of national economies through the movement of people, ideas, capital, technology, goods, and services. Globalization so defined has already crossed a threshold from which it will likely never return, barring a global conflict or a failure to respond adequately to climate change. Indeed, individuals across the world today are more connected than ever before. Consider, for example, that almost two-thirds of the world’s population owns a smartphone, or that the estimated number of international tourists in 2023 exceeds 1 billion. Such human interconnectivity will only increase over time as communication and transportation-related technologies continue to advance. There has also been rapid growth in services trade, and especially in intermediate services.1 When observed through this broad lens, globalization remains deeply rooted and change is one of its enduring characteristics.

Among the many facets of globalization, our focus is on international trade, and on global value chains (GVCs) in particular. The volume of trade flows in goods and services has withstood significant challenges in the past, and stands to do the same in the future, even as patterns of trade flows change. Already, many of the negative impacts of the COVID-19 pandemic and increased geopolitical tensions have been met with creative workarounds, demonstrating the resilience of international trade and global supply networks. Changes in the patterns of cross-border trade in goods and services do not indicate a decline in globalization. Our quantitative analysis provides strong evidence that value-added trade supporting the production of goods and services did not recede during 2000-2021, nor was there evidence of a global trend toward reshoring. Instead, the evidence suggests that 2021 was a high mark for the global exchange of goods and services as measured by international value-added production linkages. Regarding the question of whether there has been a decoupling between North America and China, our analysis finds no evidence of decoupling of value-added production linkages. In fact, we find that China and North America increased their value-added production linkages between 2017 and 2021, implying significantly greater linkages than those that could be estimated using gross trade statistics.

Our analysis utilizes the GVC Indicators database created by the University of International Business and Economics (UIBE) in Beijing. The GVC Indicators database breaks down value added into that which flows through GVCs, and that which does not.2 See the appendix for a description of the data and methodology. In the charts that follow, the term “forward GVC participation” captures the degree to which a country’s domestic value added is exported through global value chains. “Backward GVC participation” captures the extent to which a country’s final production includes value added that is imported from global value chains. For each measurement, a higher percentage indicates greater relative importance of value added that is imported or exported through GVCs compared to value added sourced domestically. Thus, higher levels of backward and forward GVC participation indicate greater global integration of production networks.

We concentrate on the world’s three major trading entities: China, the European Union (EU), and North America, defined as the three nations in the USMCA (Canada, Mexico, and the United States). Our calculations for the EU in all years include GVC activity for the 27 member countries as of 2021, and therefore exclude the United Kingdom. Value added originating from China, the EU, and North America accounted for 54% of worldwide value added involved in GVCs in 2021, and final production by the three entities accounted for 57% of GVC-involved final production. Other significant GVC trading nations in 2021 which are not included in our main analysis include India, Japan, Russia, and the United Kingdom.3 In our analysis, we address reshoring within North America and the EU while considering how each bloc’s linkages with China have evolved over time.

To read the full paper, see below. 

Globalization and International Value Chains - Erb Sommers

Guy Erb is a former U.S. trade policy official and investment banker.
Scott Sommers is a PhD student in Economics at the University of Minnesota.

To read the full paper, please click here.

The post Globalization and International Value Chains: 2000-2021 appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Global Trade in 2023: What’s Driving Reglobalization? /atp-research/global-trade-in-2023/ Mon, 30 Jan 2023 05:00:14 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=35858 Summary Global trade will continue to face multiple challenges in 2023 as inflation and high interest rates, debt distress and geopolitical frictions weigh on many economies. The downside risks to...

The post Global Trade in 2023: What’s Driving Reglobalization? appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Summary

Global trade will continue to face multiple challenges in 2023 as inflation and high interest rates, debt distress and geopolitical frictions weigh on many economies. The downside risks to the global economy and international trade are significant, ranging from an escalation of Russia’s war on Ukraine to deepening tensions between the US and China.

‘Reglobalization’ – rather than deglobalization – best describes the current pattern of economic integration and fracturing across different economies and sectors. Globalization is far from finished, but will increasingly emphasize greater regional links and the formation of economic blocs for sensitive and strategically important sectors. Comprehensive decoupling from China is neither achievable nor desirable for the G7 and like-minded partners.

The supply-chain disruptions of 2020–22 will continue to ease. Given that extreme weather events are the biggest threat to global production networks, supply-chain resilience and diversification efforts will persist, with added impetus to act on ‘greening’ trade.

The future of trade is closely linked to the transition to green and digital economies. As climate ambitions and technological leadership are intertwined with industrial policy objectives, concerns about unfair trade practices and protectionism are coming to a head not just as regards China, but also among the US, the EU and like-minded partners.

With major breakthroughs at the World Trade Organization unlikely in 2023, limited progress can be expected in some bilateral, regional and sectoral agreements. Meanwhile, efforts to avoid further trade fragmentation will progress more readily under Japan’s G7 presidency than under India’s G20 presidency.

Introduction

This briefing paper analyses the outlook for global trade in 2023, and examines the structural forces shaping global trade and globalization more broadly.

It argues that ‘reglobalization’ – rather than deglobalization – best describes the current and likely future pattern of economic integration and fracturing across different economies and sectors. Trade policy has an important role to play in underpinning the positive aspects of a reglobalized world and in balancing geopolitical competition and cooperation, not just through coordinated efforts to strengthen supply-chain resilience, but also in harnessing the twin transitions to green and digital economies.

The paper draws on insights from expert roundtable discussions and a high-level speaker series under the umbrella of the Chatham House Global Trade Policy Forum. It is the first of a new annual series that will highlight some of the major global trade trends and prospects for the year(s) ahead.

Marianne Schneider-Petsinger is a senior research fellow in the Global Economy and Finance Programme at Chatham House, responsible for analysis at the nexus of political and economic issues. Before joining Chatham House in 2016, she managed the Transatlantic Consumer Dialogue, an international membership body representing consumer organizations in the EU and the US. She also worked for a think-tank on transatlantic affairs in the US, and for the Thuringian Ministry of Economic Affairs in Germany.

To read the full report, please click here.

The post Global Trade in 2023: What’s Driving Reglobalization? appeared first on WITA.

]]>
The Death of Globalisation? You Won’t Find it in New Orleans. /atp-research/globalisation-in-new-orleans/ Sat, 21 Jan 2023 20:32:19 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=35851 NEW ORLEANS — The pandemic-era collapse of supply chains spurred speculation that globalization was on the decline, as companies vowed to become less reliant on foreign providers of goods and...

The post The Death of Globalisation? You Won’t Find it in New Orleans. appeared first on WITA.

]]>
NEW ORLEANS — The pandemic-era collapse of supply chains spurred speculation that globalization was on the decline, as companies vowed to become less reliant on foreign providers of goods and services. But if New Orleans is any example, the world is headed for less of a retreat from global trade and more of an overhaul to how it operates.

A critical gateway between the Mississippi River and global oceans, New Orleans has been an entry and exit point for the United States since before the Louisiana Purchase. The city is now betting that position will continue — and even deepen — as the world enters a new era of global integration.

The New Orleans port is one of the nation’s busiest for agricultural exports like soybeans and corn. But it has struggled to compete for the lucrative imports that are ferried on huge ships from Asia, in part because those vessels cannot fit under a local bridge. As global supply chains rearrange in the pandemic’s wake, New Orleans’ proximity to Mexico and its position on the Mississippi River could help make it a crucial stop in what many expect to be a more resilient supply chain of the future.

Jeanna Smialek writes about the Federal Reserve and the economy for The New York Times. She previously covered economics at Bloomberg News, where she also wrote feature stories for Businessweek magazine.

Ana Swanson writes about trade and international economics for The New York Times. She previously covered the economy, trade and the Federal Reserve for The Washington Post.

This piece was originally posted on the New York Times. 

To read the full article, click here

The post The Death of Globalisation? You Won’t Find it in New Orleans. appeared first on WITA.

]]>
Toward Multipurpose Trade Policy? How Competing Narratives About Globalization are Reshaping International Trade Cooperation /atp-research/trade-policy-narratives-reshaping-trade/ Sun, 15 Jan 2023 20:24:46 +0000 /?post_type=atp-research&p=39210 A new approach to trade policy is taking shape—multipurpose trade policy. Nicolas Lamp, associate professor at Queen’s University, highlights the evidence for this paradigm shift in trade policy, outlines the...

The post Toward Multipurpose Trade Policy? How Competing Narratives About Globalization are Reshaping International Trade Cooperation appeared first on WITA.

]]>
A new approach to trade policy is taking shape—multipurpose trade policy. Nicolas Lamp, associate professor at Queen’s University, highlights the evidence for this paradigm shift in trade policy, outlines the key challenges that it presents, and explores its implications for international trade cooperation.

After years of upheaval in international economic relations, a new approach to trade policy is taking shape: multipurpose trade policy. Inspired by competing narratives about globalization that bring different values to the fore, this approach no longer just tries to achieve an efficient international division of labour through trade liberalization. Rather, it tasks trade policy with achieving other substantive policy objectives as well, which include bolstering labour rights, addressing inequality, building resilient supply chains, safeguarding national security, and mitigating the climate crisis.

Trade officials have long been attentive to the effects of trade on other policy objectives, often portraying them as either positive or negative externalities of trade liberalization. On the positive side, increased international interdependence was expected to promote peaceful international relations. Some expected that rising incomes would lead to better working conditions and more support for environmental protection. Others argued that trade produced negative externalities, such as the overexploitation of resources and environmental degradation, and advocated for the expansion of exceptions to trade obligations to resolve conflicts between trade and other objectives. Since the early 1990s, trade agreements have also often featured provisions regarding labour rights and the environment to ensure that greater international competition does not take place on “unfair” terms.

The key distinguishing feature of the more recent shift to multipurpose trade policy is that other policy objectives no longer come into the picture as externalities of trade liberalization or as safeguards against unfair competition. Instead, those other policy objectives have taken a place alongside, and in some cases the place of, trade liberalization as the immediate objectives that trade policy is supposed to pursue.

The purpose of this article is to sketch the evidence for this paradigm shift in trade policy, outline the key challenges that it presents, and explore its implications for international trade cooperation.

The Crisis of Globalization

It is now commonplace to observe that globalization is in crisis. One piece of evidence of this crisis is that the establishment view of globalization as an inevitable force for good is increasingly being challenged by other narratives that bring a range of competing values to the fore. From the economic establishment’s perspective, free trade and an efficient international division of labour have the potential to make everyone better off—if governments implement the right policies domestically to help workers adjust to the dislocations that competition in a truly global economy may cause.

As Anthea Roberts and I show in our book Six Faces of Globalization, many other narratives are testing this view. There are those who argue that the damage that job losses cause to certain groups of workers outweighs the benefits of cheaper products and additional economic opportunities that globalization may create in other places and for other professions. Another narrative maintains that the investment and intellectual property protections in international economic agreements contribute to rising inequality. There are also rising concerns about the security implications of international economic interdependence; Russia’s invasion of Ukraine is only the latest illustration of why it may be unwise to become overly reliant on a trading partner whom one cannot trust. Yet others point out how the COVID-19 pandemic has exposed the fragility of global supply chains and our economic systems’ lack of resilience to shocks. And finally, the drumbeat of news about floods, droughts, extreme heat, and wildfires provides a daily reminder of how the global diffusion of Western patterns of production and consumption has set the world on a path to climate breakdown.

The Turn to Multipurpose Trade Policy

We can understand the shift to multipurpose trade policy as a response to these narratives. As European Union Director General for Trade Sabine Weyand has written, it is now “normal to ask what trade can do to address the big tests of our time. How can it help combat climate change? How can it promote labour rights globally? How does it impact security?” Weyand notes that “trade is seen as a tool to attain broader objectives more than ever.” Trade policy is increasingly moving away from efficiency as its primary objective. United States Trade Representative Katherine Tai has argued that the pursuit of efficiency has created a “quite fragile global economy” and that “in refashioning globalization to a Globalization 2.0 … we [need to] adapt the rules of trade to incentivize firm behavior to take into account more than just efficiency, but to promote and to reward decisions that are made to pursue sustainability for our people and our planet.” The U.S. initiative for an Indo-Pacific Economic Framework, which the United States is negotiating with 12 countries in the region, foregrounds the objectives of “resilience,” “inclusion,” and “sustainability.” At the same time, ever more aspects of U.S. trade policy are dominated by considerations of national security, especially in its relationship with China.

Multipurpose trade policy also plays an increasingly prominent role in the World Trade Organization (WTO). The Agreement on Fisheries Subsidies is the first WTO agreement that primarily pursues a sustainability objective. In the wake of the global supply chain crisis and rising food and energy prices, food security has taken a much more prominent place on the WTO’s agenda. And the debate about how the WTO can help its members do a better job of weathering the next pandemic is in full swing.

Not all new objectives enjoy universal support. While some goals, such as sustainability and resilience, are broad enough to garner virtually universal assent, others, such as the use of trade measures to promote labour rights or shore up national security, are more controversial. Even on the widely supported objectives, there is disagreement on how best to achieve them. However, the bottom line is that trade policy is now expected to pursue a much broader range of objectives than even a few years ago.

Nicolas Lamp is an Associate Professor at the Faculty of Law of Queen’s University in Ontario, Canada.

To read the full policy analysis, please click here.

The post Toward Multipurpose Trade Policy? How Competing Narratives About Globalization are Reshaping International Trade Cooperation appeared first on WITA.

]]>